1 / 42

Migration, Risk-Sharing and Subjective Well-being Some evidence from India 1975-2005

Migration, Risk-Sharing and Subjective Well-being Some evidence from India 1975-2005. Stefan Dercon, University of Oxford Pramila Krishnan, Cambridge University Sonya Krutikova , Oxford University. ICRISAT, India.

dacia
Download Presentation

Migration, Risk-Sharing and Subjective Well-being Some evidence from India 1975-2005

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Migration, Risk-Sharing and Subjective Well-beingSome evidence from India 1975-2005 Stefan Dercon, University of Oxford Pramila Krishnan, Cambridge University Sonya Krutikova, Oxford University

  2. ICRISAT, India • 6 villages, semi-arid tropics in Maharasthra and Andhra Pradesh (3 districts: Mahbubnagar, Sholapur and Akola) • Villages extensively studied, longitudinal data 1975-84 • 2005/6 and 2006/07 resurvey of all households in village plus migrants 2005/06

  3. Purpose • Briefly report on changes within villages 1975-2005 • Focus on migration from villages

  4. The data….

  5. Overview of Changes in Villages • All deflated by rural CPIAL • Quick overview of • Land and assets • Consumption • Income sources • All suggesting considerable growth VLS1 to 2005

  6. Other changes • Substantial income and consumption growth per capita (4% per capita annualised for consumption) • More than doubling in consumption per capita, with larger growth in non-food • Food share down, cereal and pulses share down (69 to 43%), animal protein up (12 to 23%) • Growth across land distribution groups • Poverty down from 78% to 18%; landless labourers down to 28%

  7. Structure of incomes Shares of Mean Income per Capita

  8. Self-Assessed Welfare Positions (2005)

  9. Conclusion • Considerable changes in village living standards and assets • Consumption poverty and self-assessed poverty down • Big changes in income sources

  10. Conclusion (2) • Regression consumption growth (recall, doubled = increased by 100%+ on average) Strong correlates (with economic significant size) • those from literate households 30% more growth • Those educated themselves up to end high school +17% • High dependence on crop income in VLS1, doing worse • Lower caste groups (SC/ST/some BC) -10 to -20%

  11. So what about Migrants? • Development correlated with internal migration • Out of agriculture • Out of rural areas “physical mobility, economic mobility, social mobility all related” • Scale required is massive: • E.g. China: last 20 years, from 80% to 55% in agriculture, much of it involving local or long-distance migration

  12. The data….

  13. Destinations of migration

  14. Reasons for migration

  15. Views on migration and inequality On evidence • Perception of slum living, low wages, high unemployment paints bleak picture of urban living • Evidence from poverty measurement suggests much higher rural than urban poverty

  16. Views on migration and inequality On theory: (a) Labour market theories • Inequality ‘drives’ migration but outcome is equilibrium – so why higher rural poverty? • Inequality drives migration without resolving it (HT) (b) Household models • Migration is strategic family decision (NEM) • with risk-sharing and remittances as one of its reflections – so strong prediction on intra-household inequality (not growing) (RS)

  17. The questions • Is there a migration premium? • Is it consistent with standard theory models? From long-term longitudinal data tracking all within families, data of up 30 years... • Evidence: • of relatively large migration, large “returns” to migration, including for female migrants • with a twist on the theory (  or  )

  18. Empirical challenge • Wages for urban and rural hard to compare (differentiated labour markets in skills, tasks, etc) • We need to ensure we have counterfactual: living standards if migrant had not migrated • Migrants could be from better families • M could be those with higher earnings potential • Setting up via ‘family (risk) sharing model’ as it offers means of both exploiting data and theory predictions • Focusing on consumption and subjective well being (“net of remittances”)

  19. Model • Suppose we have an extended family group that is in involved in perfect (risk) sharing. Let us characterize the outcome and then use this as a basis for testing deviations from this. • Let there be (different) (risky) income streams yi for each household i in a group. (Suppose there is no savings.) • Suppose now that these households contract with each other to get optimal (risk) sharing, and assuming that the contract is enforceable (binding sharing rule).

  20. model (2)

  21. “Overidentification” by location: if sharing, location should not matter, or β=0

  22. Taking to data... • Model can be used for risk-sharing, but test nests more general ‘premium’ test β=0 tests sharing, irrespective of location But also test for presence of migrant premium, ceteris paribus, as if in a difference-in-difference framework

  23. Empirical application? • Following Beegle, Dercon, De Weerdt, RESTAT 2011 on Tanzania • Initial household fixed effects estimator • With further IV for time varying individual heterogeneity

  24. Assessing the impact of migration m • Changes in consumption, not levels (in real terms) = control for time-invariant factors that determine levels (diff-in-diff) • Initial household fixed effects, to compare the impact of migration between family members initially living together (γj) = control for all factors that determine changes common to all those initially living together (“triple difference”)

  25. Specification • - Individual baseline characteristics (Xt-1 ) = control for all observable individual (time-varying and time-invariant) factors that determine changes =individual baseline characteristics: age, sex, educationbaseline, caste, family educational and wealth background, family composition at baseline, nutrition at baseline. • One step further: individual level IV = control for unobservables at individual level determining changes

  26. Returns to migration….

  27. Specification IV -Instruments = control for unobservables at individual level determining changes = predictors of migration, not directly determining ‘incomes’ = predictors explaining why member x went and not member y = relational variables (birth order) plus push factor interacted with age window at baseline: rainfall at the age of 16 First stage, strongly significant, Cragg-Donald 9.42 Results: 0.67 for men, 0.65 for women (sign 1%)

  28. Answers • Is there a premium to migration? (HT): YES • Is this premium fully exploited? NO • Are families smoothing over space? (RS): NO But not a simple story of educational investment (life-cycle), sectoral, urban-rural shift... Intra-Family Inequality after migration High premium ‘unexploited’ • So Why Undermigration? Theory just wrong?

  29. Are we getting the point? • They are not ‘sharing’ in space? But what if ‘location’ matters per se? Location as a taste shifter?

  30. Are we getting the point? • For example: “urban needs” • As in “keeping up with the Jones’ consumption ” • Are they ‘sharing’ in this space? • If θ(location), then finding migration effect could be consistent with risk-sharing • Can we test? • Do we have data closer to bist cistγ, and not just cist? • Possibly via subjective wellbeing data! • We would expect that this ‘controls’ for taste shifter better, so no more migration effect.

  31. Assessing the impact of migration m • we have data on changes in perceived wealth • we also have data on levels of happiness, life evaluation, etc.

  32. Subjective assessment of wealth

  33. Subjective assessment of wealth

  34. Nostalgia bias? • Results may be affected by recall. • Can we use cross-section? Needs strong assumption on observability of pareto weight

  35. Nostalgia bias? • Alternatively: when living together, no compensation for subjective well-being. We treat is as if we were all in initial household at similar subjective wellbeing (and so in fixed effect)

  36. Perceived wealth and happiness IHHFE

  37. Interpretation • OVERALL consistent with sharing!!! • Migration lowers subjective well being (how one assess own wealth) =Consistent with subjective well-being =relative concept =Could reflect more difficult conditions (being outsider,...) =could reflect ‘relative’ comparison but also huge nostalgia effect • As a migrant, your initial family ‘allows’ you to have a huge consumption premium, to compensate you for your miserable existence (taste shifter) • Consistent with literature on subjective wellbeing as relative experience

  38. Overall conclusion • Families may allow inequality to emerge as part of ‘sharing’ strategy • HERE: with higher material wellbeing to compensate for otherwise lower overall or subjective wellbeing • Still: UNDERmigration in terms of material wellbeing (given seemingly high returns) • Policy?

More Related