1 / 108

Utility Maximization

Utility Maximization. A Utility Function Mathematically Representing Preferences. U. U=U(x, y). U(A). Y. U(B). Utility functions have. A. Indifference curves describe bundle-ordering preferences. B. X. Consumption Opportunities: The Budget Constraint.

Download Presentation

Utility Maximization

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Utility Maximization

  2. A Utility Function Mathematically Representing Preferences U U=U(x, y) U(A) Y U(B) Utility functions have A Indifference curves describe bundle-ordering preferences B X

  3. Consumption Opportunities: The Budget Constraint • Assume that an individual has I dollars to allocate between good x and good y pxx+ pyyM y The individual can afford to choose only combinations of x and y in the shaded triangle x

  4. The Budget Constraint • MC of consuming one more unit of x, the amount of y that must be foregone. • The slope of the budget line is this MC. y The slope is the change in y for a one unit increase in the consumption of x. If Px= 10 and Py= 5, then consuming one more x means consuming two less y. x

  5. Maximizing Utility • Keep buying x until the MB(x) = MC(x) • Interaction of… • Preferences, diminishing MB because of diminishing MRS. MB = MRS • MB in terms of y willing to be given up • In dollars, MB = py*MRS • MC of x = px/py • MC in terms of Y given up • In dollars, MC = px. MB, MC Not an indifference curve! MC MB X X*

  6. Optimization Principle • To maximize utility, given a fixed amount of income, an individual will buy the goods and services: • That exhaust total income • Savings or borrowing is allowed (if we modify the budget constraint to include a temporal component) • So long as MB(x) ≥ MC(x), MB(y) ≥ MC(y), etc. • Or, until MB(x) = MC(x), MB(y) = MC(y)

  7. Intuition • MRS is the maximum amount of y the person is willing to give up to consume more x; the definition of MB. • px/py tells us the number of units of y that must be given up to consume one more x; the definition of MC. y A At “A”, MRS>Px/Py (MB > MC), You are willing to pay more than you have to, consumer surplus increases. • Utility and consumer surplus • can be increased by consuming more x. At “B”, MRS<Px/Py, (MB < MC) Utility and consumer surplus can be increased by consuming less x. B Px= 10 Py= 5 Slope of budget line = -2 U0 x

  8. Intuition • At “C”, the MB = MC for the last unit of both goods consumed. • That is, at “C”, MRS = px/py, or y A C U1 B U0 x

  9. Optimization • Unconstrained optimization is a lot easier to solve than constrained optimization. • Substitution: maximize the cross section of U along the budget line • Lagrange method

  10. Substitution • This turns the constrained optimization into an unconstrained problem. • Find the equation for the cross section of the U=U(x,y) above the budget line and maximize it -- i.e. find the top of the parabola U y y* x* x

  11. Substitution • Substitute and maximize And substitute again

  12. Problem with this method • It can get very mathematically complicated very quickly. • Even U=xαyβ gets very tricky to solve.

  13. LaGrange Method • LaGrange knew that unconstrained optimization (like profit max) is relatively simple compared to constrained optimization. • Taking what he knew unconstrained optimization he attempted to simplify the constrained maximization problem by making it mimic the unconstrained problem.

  14. Unconstrained Optimization Example • Profit maximization is an example of this. We maximize the difference between two functions: π=R(q) – C(q).

  15. Lagrange Method • LaGrange wanted to find a way that was simpler than constrained optimization and more workable than simple substitution. • He wanted to make constrained optimization take the form of the simpler unconstrained problem. • First, let’s look at a simpler problem.

  16. Maximize Utility - Expenditure • Maximize utility minus the cost of buying bundles. Think about a one-good world. U U=U(x) • slope =Ux Expenditure = E = pxx • slope = Ex=px • Problems: • Ux not measured in $ like E. • E is not constrained, we can spend as much as we like. x x*

  17. Maximizing Utility - Expenditure • First change the expenditure function by multiplying px by λ. Now call that function EU. • We want λ to measure the marginal utility of $1. • In that case, units of x consumed would cost us utility and both U(x) and EU(x) would be measured in the same units. U U=U(x) • slope =Ux EU=λpxx • Slope = EUx= λpx x x*

  18. Maximizing Utility - Expenditure • Problem, an infinite number of λ choices that will each solve this with a different x* • EUx= λ1px U U=U(x) • EUx= λ2px • EUx= λ3px x x* x* x* • Now the slope of the expenditure function and expenditure are • measured in utils, not dollars. But we are not constraining x yet.

  19. LaGrange Method • So first subtract λM from the expenditure function to get EL = λpxx - λM U U=U(x) • slope =Ux EU = λpxx EL = λpxx - λM x x* • slope = ELx= λpx -λM

  20. LaGrange Method • We know we want to find the x* such that that distance between U(x) and EL(x*) = U(x*). That is, where EL(x*) = 0 • So we maximize v = U(x) - 0 • Substitute λpxx – λM = 0 in for 0, to constrain x* to our budget. U U=U(x) • slope =Ux U=U(x*)-0 EL = λpxx - λM 0 x x* • slope = ELx= λ px -λI

  21. LaGrange Method • Our optimization becomes an unconstrained problem by including the requirement that λpxx = λM. • λ is chosen along with x to maximize utility so that λ = the marginal utility of $1. That is, λpx = Ux. U U=U(x) • slope =Ux U=U(x*)-0 EL = λ(pxx –M) 0 x x* • slope = ELx= λ px -λM

  22. LaGrange Method

  23. Two Goods: Lagrange’s Manufactured Plane • To maximize utility, maximize the height of the utility function above the plane EL = λpxx + λpyy – λM • Such that λpxx + λpyy – λM = 0 U U = U(x,y) y When x = 0 and y = 0, U = -λM • ELy=λ py LaGrange Plane • EL=g(x,y) • EL= λpxx+λpyy- λM • g’x=ELx=λ px • g’y=ELy=λ py • ELx=λ px x

  24. Lagrange Method U U = U(x,y) y • UL=g(x,y) = 0 λ(pxx+pyy– M) = 0 x

  25. Basic Demand Analysis • Using Lagrangian to generate ordinary (Marshallian) demand curves. • FOCs necessary • SOCs sufficient (check that they hold) • Ordinary (Marshallian) demand curves • Inverse demand curves • Meaning of λ • Indirect Utility • Expenditure Function • Comparative Statics General Results

  26. Demand Functions using Lagrange’s Method • Set up and maximize: λ* chosen so that the constraint plane is parallel to the utility function. Any x* and y* that maximizes utility will also have to exhaust income.

  27. FOCs for an Optimum • For utility to be maximized, it is necessary that the indifference curve is tangent to the budget constraint (as above). • But it is not sufficient, we also need a diminishing MRS. FOCs satisfied Utility Maximized y Utility Maximized y y FOCs satisfied x x x

  28. SOCs for an Optimum • Sufficient condition for a maximum to exist • If the MRS is non-increasing (utility function quasi concave) for all x, that is sufficient for a maximum to exist – but it may not be unique. • If the MRS is diminishing (utility function strictly quasi concave) for all x, that is sufficient for a unique maximum to exist. Need this to satisfy second order conditions for maximization. SOCs do not hold Utility Maximized y y y SOCs satisfied x x x

  29. Expenditure Minimization: SOC • The FOC ensure that the optimal consumption bundle is at a tangency. • The SOC ensure that the tangency is a minimum, and not a maximum by ensuring that away from the tangency, along the budget line, utility falls. U*>U’ Y U=U* U=U’ X

  30. Checking SOC:utility function strictly quasi-concave • The second order conditions will hold if the utility function is strictly quasi-concave • A function is strictly quasi-concave if its bordered Hessian is negative definite. That is: • A function is strictly quasi-concave if: • -UxUx < 0 • 2UxUxyUy - Uy2Uxx- Ux2Uyy > 0

  31. Checking SOC:Constrained Maximization • The second order condition for constrained maximization will hold if the following bordered Hessian matrix is negative definite: Note: So this Hessian and The last only differ by 

  32. Ordinary Demand Curves • And from the FOC:

  33. Inverse Demand Curves • Starting with the ordinary demand curves:

  34. Utility and Indirect Utility • Maximum Utility, a function of quantities • Indirect Utility a function of price and income

  35. Optimization :Expenditure Function • Start with indirect utility • Solve for M: • This equation determines the expenditure needed to generate Ū, the expenditure function:

  36. Digression: Envelope Theorem • Say we know that y = f(x; ω) • We find y is maximized at x* = x(ω) • So we know that y* = y(x*=x(ω),ω)). • Now say we want to find out • So when ω changes, the optimal x changes, which changes the y* function. • Two methods to solve this…

  37. Digression: Envelope Theorem • Start with: y = f(x; ω) and calculate x*= x(ω) • First option: • y = f(x; ω), substitute in x* = x(ω) to get y*= y(x(ω); ω): • Second option, turn it around: • First, take then substitute x* = x(ω) into yω(x ; ω) to get • And these two answers are equivalent:

  38. Envelope Result, 1st option to get • Plug the optimal values into the LaGrangian

  39. Optimization: Envelope Result • Plug the optimal values into the LaGrangian

  40. Optimization: Comparative Statics • If we have a specified utility function and we derive the equations for the demand functions, the comparative statics are easy. • Take the derivatives to calculate the changes in x and y when prices or income change. • However, what if all we know is U = U(x, y) and we feel safe only assuming: Ux> 0 Uy> 0 Uxx< 0 Uyy< 0 • Can we get anything from that?

  41. Optimization: Comparative Statics • Start with:

  42. Comparative Statics:Utility Maximizing x*, y*, λ*

  43. Comparative Statics: Effect of a change in MDifferentiate (1), (2), (3) w.r.t. M Side note: Tells us that if income increases by $1, so will total expenditure.

  44. Comparative Statics: Effect of a change in MPut in Matrix Notation • Solve for

  45. Comparative Statics: Effect of a change in IPut in Matrix Notation • Solve for

  46. Comparative Statics: Effect of a change in pxDifferentiate (1), (2), (3)w.r.t. px

  47. Comparative Statics: Effect of a change in pxPut in Matrix Notation • Solve for

  48. Comparative Statics: Effect of a change in pxPut in Matrix Notation… AGAIN • Solve for

  49. Comparative Statics:Preview of income and substitution effects Rearrange these Sub in these Income effect matters

  50. Specific Utility Functions • Cobb-Douglas • CES • Perfect Compliments

More Related