1 / 14

THE ECONOMIC RETURN ON INVESTMENTS IN HIGHER EDUCATION: Understanding The Internal Rate of Return

THE ECONOMIC RETURN ON INVESTMENTS IN HIGHER EDUCATION: Understanding The Internal Rate of Return. Presentation OISE, HEQCO, MTCU Research Symposium Defining and Measuring Student Success Toronto November 22, 2013 Torben Drewes Department of Economics Trent University. Background.

fran
Download Presentation

THE ECONOMIC RETURN ON INVESTMENTS IN HIGHER EDUCATION: Understanding The Internal Rate of Return

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. THE ECONOMIC RETURN ON INVESTMENTS IN HIGHER EDUCATION:Understanding The Internal Rate of Return Presentation OISE, HEQCO, MTCU Research Symposium Defining and Measuring Student Success Toronto November 22, 2013 Torben Drewes Department of Economics Trent University

  2. Background • Much public discussion about the financial viability of investments made by young Canadians in higher education (esp. university) • The term “returns to higher education” occurs often in that discussion • What exactly does that term mean? • How are such returns estimated? • How useful are such estimates?

  3. Definitions • “Return to education” often used loosely. • 2011 NHS – average annual wage and salary income for: • high school graduates: $31,400 • college graduates: $50,646 • university graduates: $62,340 • Average college incomes are 61% higher than high school incomes. The “return” to a college diploma is a 61% gain in income. • Should be termed the “earnings premium”, not the return. • After all, income comparisons do not consider the cost of the investment. • The internal rate of return on an investment or project is the "annualized effective compounded return rate" or discount rate that makes the net present value of all cash flows (both positive and negative) from a particular investment equal to zero. • I.e. the interest rate at which the net present value of costs (negative cash flows) of the investment equals the net present value of the benefits (positive cash flows) of the investment.

  4. Definitions • Why the confusion between earnings premium and irr? • Regressing the natural logarithm of earnings against measures of schooling attainment produces the proportional increase in earnings for each unit change in education: the earnings premium. • Jacob Mincer (HCEF): under certain assumptions (eg., no tuition, schooling is measured in years, etc.) the coefficient on the measure of education is the IRR. • Those assumptions do not typically hold. • earnings premium from a regression model are not equal to IRR.

  5. The IRR Calculation • Consider an annual series of cash flows, Ct, that can be negative or positive. • The IRR solves for the value of ρ so that • Your brother-in-law wants to borrow $100. Promises to repay you $110 in one year. What is the IRR to you on this investment? • Solve So ρ = 0.10, or 10% • Why is the IRR useful? The brother-in-law proposes a different repayment schedule: $56 in one year and $58 in two years. How to compare? • Solve. ρ = 0.09, or 0% • Let’s try something a little more complicated ….

  6. Let’s Increase University Tuition

  7. Estimation • Use regression or other smoothing techniques applied to Census data to produce age-earnings profiles. • Out-of-pocket (C1) and opportunity (C2) costs are compared to earnings gains (B) to compute IRR.

  8. The Caveats • Parameters Matter. • Estimates use “prototypical” decision-maker – age 18. • Eg.: returns to adult learning will be lower • Only earnings/tuition data are used. • Non-monetary costs and benefits are important, but hard to measure • Implies that IRR calculations are only part of the story. • Only private returns • Correct if we are trying to model individual decision or inform young decision-makers. • Incorrect if we are trying to evaluate public policy to promote higher education as social investment. • Need to compare social costs (different than tuition) with social benefits (gross income, reduced health expenditures, implications for productivity of co-workers, etc.)

  9. The Caveats • Future stream of earnings unknown. • Proxied by current earnings of older workers. • The Missing Counterfactual • The high school profile is what the university graduate would have earned had she entered the labour market after high school. • University (and college) graduates may differ from high school completers in other ways that are related to earnings. The ability bias issue. • Average vs Marginal Returns • Estimated returns are averages across all individuals participating in higher education. • Policy question may need to estimate returns at the margin. Eg. should we expand access to higher education?

  10. The Caveats • Estimates are average rates of return. There will be large differences across and within fields of study Distribution of real earnings (20th, 50th and 80th percentiles) by field of study for Canadian-born male bachelor’s graduates in 2005 dollars, population aged 25-64 in the labour force: Census 1985 to 2005Bell, King, Afshar, (2011), POSTSECONDARY EDUCATION AND THE LABOUR MARKET: THE EVOLUTION OF SUPPLY AND DEMAND, 1985 TO 2005, HRSDC

  11. Conclusions • Given these difficulties, should we dump the IRR? • No! • Conceptually, IRR to higher education is a valuable theoretical construct in understanding demand for PSE • For good policy design, statistical evidence trumps anecdotal evidence. • More work needed on empirical implementation, but we need the estimates. • What does that statistical evidence look like?

More Related