1 / 30

Austrian Working Group on Banking and Finance (AWG) 23. Workshop (12. - 13. 12. 2008)

Austrian Working Group on Banking and Finance (AWG) 23. Workshop (12. - 13. 12. 2008) Vienna University of Technology. Mean-Variance Asset Pricing after Variable Taxes. Christian Fahrbach christian.fahrbach@web.de Vienna University of Technology. Contents. 1 Initial question

kenley
Download Presentation

Austrian Working Group on Banking and Finance (AWG) 23. Workshop (12. - 13. 12. 2008)

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Austrian Working Group on Banking and Finance (AWG) 23. Workshop (12. - 13. 12. 2008) Vienna University of Technology Mean-Variance Asset Pricing after Variable Taxes Christian Fahrbach christian.fahrbach@web.de Vienna University of Technology

  2. Contents 1 Initial question 2 Standard model (CAPM) • Model extension 4 CAPM after variable taxes 5 Conclusion

  3. 1 Initial Question Facing stagnation and high volatility on stock markets, the following question arises: Are risky assets still attractive (competitive) compared with deposit and current accounts, call money, bonds and other assets with low risk? If not, is it possible to set up a favourable tax system, to stimulate risky investments and to stabilize financial markets?

  4. 2 The Standard Model (CAPM) (Sharpe 1964, Lintner 1965) (A1) There is a finite number of risky assets, short selling is allowed unlimitedly. (A2) There is a riskless asset, which can be lent and borrowed unlimitedly. Given:Er: n-vector of expected returns (n<∞), Vr: covariance matrix, rf: risk-free rate (non-stochastic).

  5. What arethe mean-variance optimal portfolios under A1 and A2? Optimization with Lagrange function (Merton 1972) Solution: two half lineson the µ-σ-plane,

  6. µ(r) rf σ(r) Figure 2.1:The portfolio frontier under A1 and A2.

  7. Capital market equilibrium Following Huang und Litzenberger (1988) investors will undertake risky investments if and only if Ermvp > rf , Ermvp = A / C , A = 1T (Vr)-1Er , C = 1T (Vr)-11 , rmvp: rate of return on the (global) minimum variance portfolio.

  8. Case 1: If Ermvp > rf , all investors buy portfolios on the capital market line (i.e., a linear combination of the market portfolio and the riskless asset). Case 2: If Ermvp ≤ rf , all investors put all their money into the riskless asset. In this case, a market portfolio and therefore a pricing formula for risky assets according to the CAPM does not exist !

  9. µ(r) market portfolio minimum variance portfolio rf σ(r) Figure 2.2: The capital market line on the µ-σ-plane ( Ermvp > rf ) .

  10. µ(r) rf minimum variance portfolio tangency portfolio σ(r) Figure 2.3: The portfolio frontier for Ermvp < rf .

  11. Huang and Litzenberger (1988): “Suppose that rf > A/C. Then no investor holds a strictly positive amount of the market portfolio. This is inconsistent with market clearing. Thus in equilibrium, it must be the case that rf < A/C and the risk premium of the market portfolio is strictly positive“. Remark: Whether or not this condition is fulfilled on real markets is an empirical issue.

  12. Conclusion ● Equilibrium does not exist a priori. ● The location of the riskless rate compared with the hyperbolic portfolio frontier in the μ-σ-plane is decisive. ● The CAPM is not a general equilibrium model. ● Is it possible to deduce equilibrium solutions for asset pricing in case the Huang-Litzenberger condition (HLC) is not fulfilled?

  13. Model Extension • How to extend the model? • → Keep the model as simple as possible, • → make further assumptions which allow the deduction of general equilibrium solutions for asset pricing. • Assertion: It suffices to modify the assumptions about risk-free lending and its taxation !

  14. Further Assumptions (A2*) There are severalriskless assets (deposit and current accounts, call money, etc.), short-selling is not allowed (i.e., restricted borrowing due to Black 1972). Definition 3.1: All possible risk-free rates are defined on rfЄ [0, ro] , ro > 0 , ro : overnight rate.

  15. (A3) Riskless assets are flat taxed (endbesteuert). (i.e., all investors face the same riskless rates after taxes). (A4) Riskless assets are variably taxed. Definition 3.2: Variable wealth tax on riskless assets, no: = f(Er, Vr, ro, c1, c2, …),noЄ (0, 1) , c1, c2, … : constants. Idea: nocontains all relevant information to ensure equilibrium after taxes.

  16. How to define a wealth tax on riskless assets? W1 = (1 + rf) Wo , rfЄ [0, ro] , W1,at = (1 + rf,at) Wo = (1 – no) W1 , noЄ (0, 1) , Wo : initial wealth, W1, W1,at : end of period wealth before and after taxes, no : wealth tax rate on riskless assets, rf , rf,at : risk-free rates before and after taxes, ↔ rf,at = (1 + rf) (1 – no) – 1 . (1)

  17. Why wealth tax ? In the worst case, Ermvp= 0 , all riskless rates must be negative, rf,at < 0 rf,at , → this can not be done with a yield tax according to current tax law but with a wealth tax, that is → only a wealth tax allows the deduction of general equilibrium solutions for asset pricing !

  18. Characteristics of a wealth tax on riskless assets: • riskless rates can become negative after taxes, • interest-free riskless assets (cash, current accounts, call money etc.) are also taxed, that is rf,at = – no , if rf = 0 , noЄ (0, 1) . → the interest-free riskless rate is always negative after taxes.

  19. Tax allowance (Freibetrag): Money (cash, current accounts, call money etc.), which is used for payment transactions remains untaxed (as long as the deposited amount does not exceed two to three monthly salaries).

  20. 4 CAPM after Variable Taxes • Equilibrium Theorem 4.1: • Under A1 – A4 the following assertions are equivalent: • There exists a general capital market equilibrium. • There is a value goЄ(-1, ro) with the following properties: • go= max rf,at and go < Ermvp . • Asset pricing is independent of rf , rfЄ [0, ro].

  21. Proof: • ↔ (2) : In equilibrium, the HLC must be fulfilled after taxes: rf,at ≤ go< Ermvp . • (2) → (3) : By contradiction (here only for Ermvp > 0), • (a) assume go* = f(rf) , rfЄ [0, ro] , • (b) in equilibrium must be: • go* = max rf,at = a · Ermvp , a Є (0, 1) , • ↔ contradiction to (a), because rmvp is an exogenious market value • → go ≠ f(rf) . “

  22. The hypothetical value go … • guarantees general equilibrium, • is independent of ro , • is not yet implemented in a real economy, → see proposition 4.1, • is still unknown, → see proposition 4.2.

  23. Proposition 4.1: Under A1 - A4 and the tax rate the following equation holds: go = ro,avt = max rf,at , ro,avt : overnight rate after variable taxes . Proof: Rearranging (2) gives go = (1+ro)(1–no)–1 = ro,at , which is identical with equation (1).

  24. Proposition 4.2: Given an arbitrary portfolio “q“, which is efficient under A1 (without A2 or A2*), then go≤ Erz(q), go≤ Erq – Rra Var(rq) , Rra : aggregate relative risk aversion (see Huang and Litzenberger 1988), rz(q): rate of return on the corresponding zero covariance portfolio, provide under A1 – A4 necessary and sufficient conditions for equilibrium.

  25. Zero-Beta-CAPM after variable taxes (Black 1972): Choose a portfolio “q“ on the upper branch of the hyperbolic frontier, then Erj = Erz(m) + βjm (Erm – Erz(m)) for Erz(m) ≥ go , if go= Erz(q) or go= Erq – Rra Var(rq) , where rj : rate of return on asset “j“, rm : anticipated market portfolio, βjm : β-factor.

  26. µ(r) hyperbolic frontier after taxes anticipated market portfolio arbitrary portfolio “q” on the upper branch goσ(r) Figure 4.1: Anticipated equilibrium after variable taxes ( go = max rf,at = ro,avt = Erz(q) ).

  27. Remarks: • The original portfolio “q“ is not efficient before taxes. •The anticipated market portfolio is a convex combination of efficient portfolios on the hyperbolic frontier. • Theovernight rate before taxes ro is still relevant to calculate the variable tax rate, no = f(ro), but not in the CAPM after variable taxes, Erj≠ f(ro). • Asset pricing after variable taxes depends exclusively on capital market parameters.

  28. Asset pricing in practice: If all investors combine risky and riskless assets, Erj = ro,avt + βjm (Erm – ro,avt) , for ro,avt = Erz(index) or ro,avt = Erindex – Rra ∙ Var(rindex) , where rindex : rate of return on a share index, Rra : aggregate relative risk aversion.

  29. Interpreting no as control variable: Because of ro,avt ≈ ro – no , → Erj ≈ ro – no + βjm (Erm – ro + no) , → if share prices rise, no is low and riskless assets are taxed moderately, → if share prices stagnate, no is high and riskless assets are taxed stronger, to give risky assets a chance to recover !

  30. 5 Conclusion • The variable tax has to be evaluated on the basis of current capital market data. • How to tax bonds, if riskless assets are variably taxed? • Option pricing after variable taxes (?) • A variable tax on riskless assets can compensate for stagnation on stock markets: → While taxing riskless assets stronger, there is more scope for the firms to consolidate their profits and to attract potential investors.

More Related