1 / 25

Institutional Design and Decision-Making Processes in Canadian Competition Policy

Institutional Design and Decision-Making Processes in Canadian Competition Policy. Edward Iacobucci and Michael Trebilcock University of Toronto. Road Map. 1) History and institutional design 2) Overview of the statute 3) Overview of institutional structure

leone
Download Presentation

Institutional Design and Decision-Making Processes in Canadian Competition Policy

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Institutional Design and Decision-Making Processes in Canadian Competition Policy Edward Iacobucci and Michael Trebilcock University of Toronto

  2. Road Map • 1) History and institutional design • 2) Overview of the statute • 3) Overview of institutional structure • 4) Critical evaluation of institutional status quo: Due process norms (Friday) • 5)Critical evaluation of institutional status quo: Systemic performance (Saturday)

  3. 1) History and Institutional Design • Canada’s had a competition statute in place since 1889 • But very little activity until 1986 reform • Passivity of competition enforcement directly related to institutional design: because of concern about intruding on provincial constitutional domains, federal law was entirely criminal • High burden of proof; adjudication by (sceptical) non-specialized criminal courts • E.g., merger that eliminated competition in a market permitted because Crown could not prove detriment to public interest

  4. History, cont. • Reform process began in late 1960s in face of considerable business opposition; reform not complete until passage of Competition Act in 1986 • 1986 statutory reform, and recent amendments in 2009, have shifted emphasis dramatically to civil from criminal law, with corresponding shift in institutions

  5. 2) Statutory Overview • Conduct either criminal or civilly reviewable • Following 2009 reforms, criminal offences restricted to hard core price-fixing and bid-rigging • Per se offences, unlike predecessor provisions which required showing of “undue” lessening of competition • Defence available if price-fixing agreement “ancillary” to broader agreement; if so, then civilly reviewable practice

  6. Statutory Overview, cont. • Other anticompetitive conduct is civilly reviewable • Need to show a lessening of competition • RPM, refusal to deal, exclusive territories (“market restriction”), tying, exclusive dealing specifically enumerated in Act • Abuse of dominance provisions serve as catch-all • Merger provisions (including explicit efficiencies defence)

  7. Statutory Overview, cont. • Criminal offenders (price-fixers) subject to fines and imprisonment • Civilly reviewable anticompetitive conduct generally subject to injunctive cease-and-desist orders, though there is now scope for “administrative monetary penalties” for abuse of dominance • Narrow scope for private single damages actions if and only if criminal offence

  8. 3) Institutional Overview • Competition Bureau, headed by Competition Commissioner, investigates criminal matters, but the Department of Public Prosecutions prosecutes • Criminal matters heard in ordinary courts, with all due process afforded other criminal accused persons

  9. Institutional Overview, cont. • Bureau also investigates civil matters • Bureau frequently settles; may choose to register “consent agreement” with Competition Tribunal, which automatically imbues settlement agreement with authority of a court order • If no settlement, Tribunal will adjudicate (bifurcated agency model) • Tribunal comprises judicial and lay members, though in theory only judges make decisions of law • Appeals lie to Federal Court of Appeal, though deference is owed to Tribunal decisions

  10. Institutional Overview, cont. • While there is statutory authorization of expedited procedures, Tribunal procedures have historically resembled court hearings; some push to change in recent years • Very few matters are heard by Tribunal • Eg, five contested mergers since 1986; five contested abuse cases over same period; no substantive competition cases at all in 2008

  11. Institutional Overview, cont. • Limited right for private parties to appear before Tribunal: with leave, not mergers or abuse; none successful to date in the result  Bulk of decision-making rests with Bureau as a matter of fact: no private rights of action; very few cases before Tribunal

  12. 4) Critical Evaluation of Institutional Status Quo: Due Process Norms • Focus on civil matters; criminal engages broad panoply of ordinary protections for accused • Fresh perspective from series of interviews: all former Competition Commissioners (current refused to comment); Chair of Competition Tribunal; former economist at Tribunal and Bureau • Substantial consensus that institutional framework is not working well; much less consensus on reform • Central due process concern: accountability

  13. Due Process: Independence • Consensus is that bifurcated agency structure protects independence of decision-making well • Some minor concerns expressed about location of Bureau within Ministry of Industry: budget pressures potentially compromise independence? • No former Commissioner expressed concern about political influence over any given case, though some sympathetic to reform for systemic reasons

  14. Due Process: Accountability • Serious concerns expressed about accountability of Commissioner for case-by-case decision-making • Investigative powers are seen by some as having too few checks on Bureau’s power: eg s. 11 orders to produce documents are issued following ex parte hearing • More importantly, Tribunal is effectively a bit player • Vast majority of cases are resolved by settlement with no second look by the Tribunal: consent agreements, if entered into, are simply registered; very limited private rights of action

  15. Due Process, cont. • Some irony: one of the causes for concern about Bureau’s power is due process values at the Tribunal • Tribunal has historically granted court-like due process protections • Eg even interveners were given right to cross-examine witnesses; parties in Superior Propane merger case called almost 100 witnesses • In face of cost and delay of full court-like hearing before the Tribunal, parties generally prefer to resolve any questions with the Bureau in a settlement

  16. Due Process, cont. • Consensus on concern about accountability of de facto decision-making authority of Commissioner, but no such consensus on reform • Some fairly broad support for making Competition Commissioner a multi-member commission • But much less agreement on its authority: status quo? Fact-finder? Adjudicative authority, with right of appeal?

  17. Due Process, cont. • We are drawn to bringing greater adjudicative responsibility to Commissioners • This invites objections about degrading the impartiality of adjudication in any given case • But: • Structure adjudication procedures to protect against bias • De facto Bureau decides matters now; greater de jure integration of adjudication may engender greater independence if more cases are contested and there are rights of appeal • Independence of adjudication not a trump card (e.g., importance of expertise)

  18. 5) Critical Evaluation of Institutional Status Quo: Institutional Performance • Key due process concern, accountability in decision-making, also a problem of institutional performance • Focus now on other performance norms: expertise; predictability/transparency

  19. Expertise • Serious misgivings about expertise in Canadian competition institutions exist • Some misgivings about lack of economic sophistication at Bureau, but there is consensus that expertise at the Tribunal is inadequate • Two problems: members are not expert at time of their appointment; and do not develop expertise on the job

  20. Expertise, cont. • Judicial members of Tribunal are inexpert judges who may not ever have heard an antitrust case, yet they have sole decision-making authority over questions of law • Lay members have also not been expert in practice; instead it is seen by many as a political appointment (why this is such a plum escapes us...)

  21. Expertise, cont. • There is an important problem of self-reinforcement: because Tribunal is inexpert, parties are hesitant to appear before it, which hinders the development of expertise on the job • Lack of expertise may also contribute to the “full-court press” procedure, which in turn reduces case load: don’t have sufficient confidence in the issues to be more proactive in managing a case

  22. Predictability/Transparency • On its general approach to legal questions, Bureau is seen as relatively transparent • Eg Public draft and comment approach to enforcement guidelines • But on cases, much less transparency: matters get settled; if get anything, may be short press release, or cryptic consent agreement, but not much detail

  23. Predictability/Transparency, cont. • Lack of transparency on cases obviously impacts predictability: hard to gauge precise approach of Bureau in the past • Guidelines help, but these do not have force of law, nor do they even bind the Bureau one case to the next (notorious flip-flopping in Superior Propane case)

  24. Predictability/Transparency, cont. • Tribunal situation also contributes to unpredictability: there is very little case law • And self-reinforcing: with little case law (and inexpert adjudicators), parties do not want to take a chance before the Tribunal

  25. Reform • Substantial agreement on inadequate institutional performance; much less consensus on reform • We find greater integration of adjudicative functions within the Bureau attractive • Key: Greater expertise: adjudicators are immersed in competition policy • With more expert adjudicators, and streamlined procedures, hopefully there would be more adjudicated cases and greater transparency and predictability • Of course, concerns about adjudicative bias, but these (a) exist now; and (b) are not pivotal concerns on their own

More Related