1 / 23

[8](1): Sherman Act - Section 2

[8](1): Sherman Act - Section 2. Section 2: “Every person who shall monopolize , or attempt to monopolize , … any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony” Supreme Court interpretation

marlow
Download Presentation

[8](1): Sherman Act - Section 2

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. [8](1): Sherman Act - Section 2 • Section 2: “Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, … any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony” • Supreme Court interpretation • (1) possession of monopoly power in the relevant market • (2) willful acquisition OR maintenance of that power • (3) as distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historical accident • What is monopoly power (market power)? • ability to raise prices or reduce services • ability to drive existing competitors out of business • ability to create barriers to entry which prevent new competitors from entering

  2. [8](2): Monopolization (Section 2) • What must government or private plaintiff prove? • (1) Monopoly Power in a relevant product and geographic market • very high market share, certainly over 60%, often as much as 80% • significant natural barriers to entry for new competitors • (2) Predatory or Exclusionary Practices • predatory practices harm existing competitors, possibly driving them out of business • exclusionary practices are artificial barriers to entry that prevent new competitors • (3) Practices have no legitimate business justification • Different standard to prove attempted monopolization • (1) Current market share can be much smaller, maybe as low as 30% • (2) Dangerous Probability of Success in gaining a monopoly market share • certainly over 60% • (3) Predatory Practice designed to drive existing competitors out of business

  3. [8](3): Microsoft - Market Power • What are the product markets? • Operating systems for Intel-compatible personal computers: Windows • Internet Browsers: Netscape Navigator and Microsoft Explorer • What is the geographic market? • World-wide market, but same as U.S. market • What is Microsoft’s market share? • Operating Systems: Windows had 90% - 95% of new sales throughout 1990’s • As a result, Windows had 80% - 90% of installed base • Browser Shares: Explorer Navigator • 1995: 0% 100% • 1996: 10% 75% • 1998: 50% 50% • 2000: 60% 40%

  4. [8](4): Microsoft - Potential Competition • What is the existing competition in operating systems? • Apple: declining share except in certain niche markets • OS/2: IBM system, died with decline in IBM PC sales • Unix (Linux): popular on networks, but not common on PCs • What is the potential competition? AOL-Netscape-Java • AOL = dominant supplier of Internet access • Navigator (Netscape) = major Internet browser • Java (Sun) = flexible programming language that allows applications software to run on any operating system • What are the barriers to entry in operating systems? • Network externalities (applications barrier to entry) • Designers write new software applications for the dominant operating system • Consumers benefit from standardized operating systems and applications

  5. [8](5): Microsoft - Netscape Negotiations • Microsoft Offers a “special relationship” to Netscape (79-89) • Stop development of Navigator as a platform for applications software • In return, Microsoft will let Netscape have the “solutions” market for special commercial applications within Windows • In return, Netscape could control browser markets for Apple, OS/2, and UNIX • Problem: Joint Venture or Allocation of Markets? • Microsoft withholds technical information from Netscape (90-92) • Applications programming interfaces for Windows 95 were necessary for Netscape to design Navigator to work with Windows 95 • Netscape must postpone release of Navigator compatible with Windows 95 until after Windows 95 is released, and thus Netscape lost holiday sales • Problem: Legitimate Business Reason?

  6. [8](6): Microsoft - Explorer Marketing • Microsoft starts a crash development of Explorer (133 - 135) • $100 million per year on development of Explorer • Rapid increase in developers from 5 or 6 in early 1995 to 1000 in 1999 • Microsoft includes Explorer for free with a Windows license (137) • Bundling the Explorer Internet application to the Windows operating system • Microsoft negotiates exclusive arrangements for Explorer (139 - 142) • Microsoft allows Internet Access and Service Providers (IAPs and ISPs) to distribute Explorer for free when the enroll new customers • Microsoft provides free services to IAPs and ISPs to promote Explorer exclusively instead of Navigator • AOL adopts and promotes Explorer (until acquisition of Netscape in 1998) • Microsoft pre-installs AOL access software and icon on Windows • Microsoft pays AOL a bounty for converting Netscape customers to Explorer

  7. [8](7): Microsoft - OEMs • Contracts with OEMs for licensing Windows 95 (155 - 159) • OEMs cannot remove Explorer when pre-installing Windows • OEMs cannot remove Explorer icon • OEMs cannot modify boot sequence to load Navigator • OEMs cannot install programs to launch Navigator • Microsoft Threat to Apple Computer • Microsoft developed MAC Office for Apple PCs • MAC Office derived from its Microsoft Office • But Apple was distributing Navigator on its PCs • Microsoft threatens to discontinue development of MAC Office unless Apple exclusively distributes Explorer on its PCs • Apple agrees to distribute Explorer for its PCs

  8. [8](8): Microsoft - Explorer Integration • Microsoft redesigns Explorer for Windows 95 in 1996 (160 - 165) • Explorer shares routines with Windows • Deleting Explorer will delete important aspects of Windows • Microsoft Integrates Explorer into Windows 98 (166 - 174) • Neither OEMs nor users can uninstall or override Explorer • Installing and using Navigator interferes with Windows functions and Microsoft applications • Integration provides no benefits to users • Windows is slower and less reliable for non-browsing applications • Compromises security by making Windows more vulnerable to viruses obtained from browsing on Explorer.

  9. [8](9): Microsoft - Intel and IBM • Microsoft Offer to Intel and Threat (94 - 103) • Offer: Stop software development of NSP for video and graphics applications • In return: Microsoft would speed its development of similar applications • Threat: Microsoft will not support Intel’s next generation of microprocessors • Result: Intel discontinues NSP project • Microsoft Offer to IBM and Retaliation (115 - 130) • Offer: Stop promoting OS/2 and preinstall Windows 95 on at least half its PCs • In return: Microsoft would give IBM an $8 reduction in the royalty for Windows, with a yearly savings to IBM of $40-48 million • IBM rejected the offer, buys Lotus, promotes SmartSuite for office applications • Retaliation: Microsoft refuses to release master code for pre-installing Windows to IBM (until 15 minutes before formal release on August 24, 1995), even though other OEMs had received the master code on June 17, 1995 • IBM loses 1995 back-to-school sales of PCs to the other OEMs

  10. [8](10): Microsoft - Windows Pricing Practices • Discounts and incentives in licensing Windows 95 and 98 • Compaq and Gateway received lower license fees and promotional allowances for promoting Explorer exclusively over Navigator • Other OEMs paid higher license fees for pre-installing and promoting Navigator • IBM paid the highest license fee to pre-install Windows • Pricing by PCs shipped (Settled with JD by prior consent decree) • Microsoft charges its license fee to OEMs for pre-installation of Windows on the basis of the number of PCs shipped, rather than the number of PCs with Windows installed • As a result, Windows becomes free to pre-install on all PCs • OEM is paying the license fee to Microsoft, even if it pre-installs another operating system on the PC • Installing another operating system on the PC requires the OEM to pay a license fee for the other operating system

  11. [8](11): Microsoft - Defense • (1) No Market Power • Wider product market (include operating systems for network servers) • Actual and potential competition from existing firms (AOL-Netscape-Sun) • No barriers to entry by new firms (software designers) • Price of Windows is “low” ($89 for Windows 98, up from $49 for Windows 95) • (2) Practices are Normal Business Practices • Exclusive contracts are common for promoting products • Quantity discounts for OEMs are common for selling products • (3) Legitimate Business Reasons for Practices • Economies of integration of Windows and Explorer • Economies from standardization of operating system • compatibility and transportability of software

  12. [8](12): Microsoft - What Remedy? • Criminal Fines: Twice the gain to Microsoft? • What would have been the price of Windows? Price of Explorer was zero!!! • Criminal penalties have been extremely rare in monopolization cases because it is never obvious what will constitute a violation of Section 2 (unlike Section 1) • Structural Remedy: Divestiture? • Horizontal: License or auction Windows source code • Problem: competition may eliminate efficiencies of standardization • Vertical: Divest Windows from all applications software (Explorer) • Problem: eliminate efficiencies from integration of software • Behavioral Remedy: Injunction? • Prohibit Microsoft from making exclusive agreements with OEMs and IAPs • Provide Windows source code for applications programming interfaces (APIs) • Problem: court supervision of a technologically dynamic industry

  13. [8](13): Microsoft - District Court Decision • November 1999: District Court Findings of Fact • Judge defines market and characterizes practices in favor of JD • Judge postpones legal decision and urges settlement (none reached) • April 2000: District Court Conclusions of Law • Microsoft violated Section 2: invites proposals for a remedy • Justice Department proposes a remedy, Microsoft asks for more time • June 2000: District Court Judgment = Vertical Divestiture • Operating System Company (OpsCo): Windows • Applications Company (AppsCo): Explorer, Word, Excel, Office • Goal: eliminate the applications barrier to entry in operating systems • AppsCo will have an incentive to adapt and design applications for other operating systems and platforms • AppsCo will have an incentive to develop other operating systems and platforms

  14. [8](14): Microsoft - Final Judgment • 2001: Court of Appeals Decision • Upheld violation of Section 2 for monopolization • Reversed vertical divestiture as a remedy • Remanded to a new District Court Judge for a new hearing on remedy • November 2002: Final Judgment • New District Court judge approves new settlement between Microsoft and JD • Settlement is a behavior remedy with extensive monitoring by the JD • States lawsuit against Microsoft will continue • Certain states refused to accept the settlement negotiated by the JD • Private lawsuits against Microsoft will continue • EU is also pursuing a case against Microsoft

  15. [8](15): Behavioral Remedy • Microsoft cannot retaliate against OEMs, ISPs, or IHVs for developing or distributing other operating systems or applications software (A and F) • Microsoft must offer uniform licensing agreements to OEMs (B) • Microsoft cannot impose license restrictions on OEMs for pre-installing other software (C) • Microsoft must disclose APIs and Protocols (D and E) • Microsoft cannot enter into a large variety of exclusive contracts (G) • Microsoft must allow OEMs and users to remove and replace Microsoft applications with other competing applications (H)

  16. [8](16): U.S. v. American Airlines (2002) • What is Predatory Pricing? • Dominant firm lowers prices until its competitors go bankrupt and exit • Dominant firm then raise prices to recoup the losses • Predation also deters future entry by other potential competitors • JD sues American Airlines for monopolizing Dallas/Ft. Worth airport • American has 70% of passenger revenue to and from Dallas/Ft. Worth airport • Predatory practices in response to entry by new airlines • AA matches the lower fares of any entrant on the routes served • AA increases the number of flights on these routes to reduce load factors of entrants • Entrants experience low load factors, no profits, so they exit or go bankrupt • AA then raises fares and reduces the number of flights on these routes • American wins at trial, not guilty of monopolization • AA did not lower its fares below its costs, or below the fares of its competitors

  17. [8](17): Kodak Cases • What is an “aftermarket”? • Durable goods often require repair, service, or maintenance • Durable goods often require replacement parts • Durable goods often require consumable goods for their use • Eastman Kodak v. Image Technical Services (Kodak I) (1992) • Kodak refuses to sell replacement parts for its copy machines to independent service organizations (ISOs) • Kodak also prevents OEMs from selling parts to ISOs • Kodak also refuses to sell parts directly to customers who want to use ISOs • Kodak then monopolizes the service on its own copiers • Can an aftermarket be a relevant product market? • Supreme Court says YES!!! • Even if the manufacturer has no market power in the durable good!!!

  18. [8](18): Pricing in Aftermarkets • Suppose you are trying to sell a durable good (car) • Potential customer asks about the costs of consumable goods (gas and tires), replacement parts (engine parts), and service (tuneups) • What do you want to tell him? There are cheap!!!! • Now suppose the customer has already bought the durable good • And suppose you are the only supplier of the aftermarket goods and services • What prices do you want to charge? High prices!!! Why? • Customer is “locked in” because it is costly to switch to another durable good • Now think about installed base versus new sales • How does this affect your pricing of the aftermarket goods and services? • Low prices if the new sales are much larger than the installed base • High prices if the installed base is much larger than the new sales

  19. [8](19): Why Monopolize Aftermarkets? • Suppose you did not control the aftermarket goods and services when you introduced the durable good • You would be happy to have competitive suppliers provide them at low prices • But once the installed base of the durable good is large relative to the new sales • Revenue and profits from new sales are declining • If you controlled the aftermarkets, you could charge high prices for the aftermarket goods and services to the installed base of the durable good • Incentive to monopolize the aftermarkets in whatever way possible • Since the manufacturer often produces the replacement parts, this is a typical mechanism for monopolizing the other aftermarkets • Even if the manufacturer does not produce the parts, he often has control over the OEMs who do

  20. [8](20): Red Lion v. Ohmeda - Markets • What is the relevant product market? • Plaintiffs argue “service on Ohmeda machines” • Defendant argues “anesthesia systems”: system include machines, consumables, parts, service, and even related monitors • What does Court decide? On summary judgment • Definition of the product market requires a trial on the facts • But court clearly indicates that it is disposed to defining a service aftermarket • film (for cameras), software (for computers), and tires (for cars) are markets • Does Ohmeda have market power in service on its machines? • Yes, Ohmeda does 71% of the service on its machines • Biomeds service another 20% and ISOs only 10% • But only 46% of service on all anesthesia machines because there is another major manufacturer of machines (Drager)

  21. [8](21): Red Lion v. Ohmeda - Practices • Service Restricted Parts are the major parts of the anesthesia machines • Ohmeda Policy prior to 1997 • Ohmeda would not sell service restricted parts to ISOs • Ohmeda prohibited OEMs from selling service restricted parts to ISOs • Ohmeda required a “waiver of liability” from the hospital if a service restricted part was going to be installed by an ISO • ISOs could only provide service with non-service restricted parts • Ohmeda Policy after 1997 - after the lawsuit was filed • Ohmeda defined “qualified ISOs” as ISOs with a trained employee • Training for all Ohmeda machines costs at least $30,000 • Training classes are infrequent and often full (with biomeds) • Qualified ISOs receive no discounts on the parts and cannot advertise

  22. [8](22): Red Lion v. Ohmeda - Justifications • Does Ohmeda have Legitimate Business Justifications? • (1) Protect patients from breakdowns or accidents • Does this justification require a restrictive policy toward ISOs? • Not really, it only requires training OR certification • Ohmeda could offer the training classes more often at a lower cost • ISO employees are former service employees of Ohmeda • (2) Preserve the reputation of its machines • Does this justification makes sense? • Not really, because anesthesiologists make the decisions about which machines to buy (Ohmeda or Drager) and it would usually be a simple matter to identify the cause of any accident

  23. [8](23): Defenses in Kodak Cases • Manufacturer cannot increase the prices of aftermarket goods because he will lose sales of the durable good to other manufacturers • Customers compare “life-cycle” costs in making purchase decisions • New customers will purchase from the other manufacturers • Installed base of old customers can costlessly switch to other manufacturers • Counter arguments • Installed base is too large relative to new sales • Stronger incentive to charge high aftermarket prices • Installed base of Ohmeda machines was 10 - 15 the yearly sales • Switching by the installed base customers is not easy • Anesthesiologists have strong preferences for Ohmeda or Drager • No market for used machines - most used machines sold to developing countries • Drager has similar incentives to charge high aftermarket prices

More Related