1 / 24

Behavioral Finance

Explore the concept of fungibility and the law of one price in behavioral finance and economics, with examples from stocks, funds, and ETFs. Includes an analysis of the players' behavior and equilibrium in the market.

mesposito
Download Presentation

Behavioral Finance

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Behavioral Finance Economics 437

  2. The Law of One Price • Identical things should have identical prices • But, what if two identical things have different names? • Example: baseball, hardball • Another example: two companies with exact same cash flow but they are different companies in name, but in every other way they are different (think of two bonds, if it makes any easier to imagine)

  3. Fungibility (convertibility from one form to another) • Imagine two “different” products • Product A • Product B • Imagine a machine that you can plug A into and out comes B and you can plus B into and out comes A • This is called “fungibility” • You can easily turn one thing into another and vice versa costlessly

  4. The Mysterious Case of Royal Dutch and Shell (stocks) • Royal Dutch – incorporated in Netherlands • Shell – incorporated in England • Royal Dutch • Trades primarily in Netherlands and US • Entitled to 60% of company economics • Shell • Trades predominantly in the UK • Entitled to 40% of company economics • Royal Dutch should trade at 1.5 times Shell • But it doesn’t

  5. Open End Funds are the Typical • An investors sends cash to the mutual fund to buy a unit interest in the fund • The fund takes the investor’s cash and buys securities in exactly the same proportions as exist in the current fund • When an investor sells his unit interest, the fund liquidates shares in the funds to redeem the investor’s interest

  6. Closed End Funds • They begin by purchasing securities • Then they do an IPO to the public selling shares in the fund • After that, the fund shares are fixed in number and the shares trade in the open market

  7. Problem • No problem with open end fund. The investor buys and sells at NAV (net asset value) • Problem arises with closed end fund • Price of a share can diverge from the stock values in the fund • Begin at a premium and, over time, trade at a discount • Discount only goes away when fund is terminated

  8. ETFs (Exchange Traded Funds) • Created much like closed end funds: securities pooled together to create a fund • Then shares in the pool sold to the public • But (“creation units”) • Shares can be created • Shares can be destroyed • Permits arbitrage to solve the closed end puzzle

  9. Decifering Shleifer Chapter 2 • The assets • The players • Their behavior • Equilibrium • Profitability of the players

  10. Imagine an economy with two assets (financial assets) • A Safe Asset, s • An Unsafe Asset, u • Assume a single consumption good • Suppose that s is always convertible (back and forth between the consumption good and itself) • That means the price of s is always 1 in terms of the consumption good (that is why it is called the “safe” asset – it’s price is always 1, regardless of anything)

  11. Safe asset, s, and unsafe asset, u • Why is u an unsafe asset? • Because it’s price is not fixed because u is not convertible back and forth into the consumption good • You buy u on the open market and sell it on the open market

  12. Now imagine • Both s and u pay the same dividend, d • d is constant, period after period • d is paid with complete certainty, no uncertainty at all • This implies that neither s or u have “fundamental” risk • (If someone gave you 10 units of s and you never sold it, your outcome would be the same as if someone gave you 10 units of u)

  13. Question • Can s and u trade at different prices? • If yes, EMH is false

  14. The players • Arbitrageurs • Noise Traders

  15. Utility Functions • “Expected Utility”, not “Expected Value” • U = -e-(2λ)w Utility wealth

  16. Overlapping Generations Structure • All agents live two periods • Born in period 1 and buy a portfolio (s, u) • Live (and die) in period 2 and consume • At time t • The (t-1) generation is in period 2 of their life • The (t) generation is in period 1 of their life • So, they “overlap” t1 t2 t3 t4

  17. How many are arbitrageurs? How many are noise traders? 0 1 The total number of traders are the same as the number of real numbers Between zero and one (an infinite number) The term “measure” means the size of any interval. For example the “measure” of the interval between 0 and ½ is ½. Interestingly, the measure of a single point (a single number) is zero. The measure of the entire interval between zero and one is 1. You can think of it as a fraction of the entire interval. The measure of noise traders is µ and the measure of arbitrage traders is 1 - µ. That is, the fraction of noise traders is µ and everybody else is an arbitrage traders

  18. What is a noise trader? Pt+1 is the price of the risky asset at time t+1 Ρt+1 is the “mean misperception” of pt+! Ρt+!

  19. What is an “arbitrage trader” • Arbitrage traders “correctly” perceive the true distribution of pt+1. There is “systematic” error in estimation of future price, pt+1 • But, arbitrageurs face risk unrelated to the “true” distribution of pt+1 • If there were no “noise traders,” then there would be no variance in the price of the risky asset…..but, there are noise traders, hence the risky asset is a risky asset

  20. Arbitrageurs expectations are “correct;” noise traders expectations are “biased” Difference is ρt+1 Correct mean of pt+1

  21. The Main Issues • What happens in equilbrium • Undetermined • Some forces make pt > 1, some forces push pt < 1, result is indeterminant • Who makes more profit, arbitrageurs or noise traders? • Depends • But, it is perfectly possible for arbitrageurs to make more! • Survival?

  22. When Do Noise Traders Profit More Than Arbitrageurs? • Noise traders can earn more than arbitrageurs when ρ* is positive. (Meaning when noise traders are systematically too optimistic) • Why? • Because they relatively more of the risky asset than the arbitrageurs • But, if ρ* is too large, noise traders will not earn more than arbitrageurs • The more risk averse everyone is (higher λ in the utility function, the wider the range of values of ρ for which noise traders do better than arbitrageurs

  23. What Does Shleifer Accomplish? • Given two assets that are “fundamentally” identical, he shows a logic where the market fails to price them identically • Assumes “systematic” noise trader activity • Shows conditions that lead to noise traders actually profiting from their noise trading • Shows why arbitrageurs could have trouble (even when there is no fundamental risk)

  24. The End

More Related