1 / 41

Market Design and Analysis Lecture 3

This lecture covers topics such as Gale-Shapley marriage market model extensions, stability concepts, computational issues, multi-item market analysis, single-item market auctions, envy-freeness, competitive equilibrium, and computation algorithms.

pmorehouse
Download Presentation

Market Design and Analysis Lecture 3

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Market Design and Analysis Lecture 3 Lecturer: Ning Chen (陈宁) Email: ningc@ntu.edu.sg

  2. Last Two Lectures… Gale-Shapley marriage market mathematical model extensions (incomplete preferences, different # of M and W) solution concept: stability computational issue: G-S algorithm mathematical properties men/women optimal stable matching lattice, LP economic properties Pareto optimality, core strategic considerations 2

  3. Multi-Item Market $2 $5 $6 $3 $4 $8 How to decide prices and allocations to achieve certain economic goals? 3

  4. Multi-Item Market Market information m sellers, each has one item to sell n potential buyers, each demands at most one item for each buyer i and item j, there is a value vij meaning the max amount that i is willing to pay for item j Output: a tuple (p,x) where price vector (pj) j=1,…,m where pj is the price of item j allocation vector (xi) i=1,…,n where xi is the item that buyer i obtains xi = Ø denotes i obtains nothing xi ≠ xj for all i and j (unless they are Ø) 4

  5. Single Item Market When there is only one item, i.e., m = 1, the problem degenerates to auction a single item Solutions: first price auction, second price auction,... Fairness guaranteed by the first and second price auction: no buyer envies other buyer’s allocation for the given charged price. That is, (e.g., in first price auction) if v1 ≥ v2 ≥ v3 ≥ ... ≥ vn buyer 1 wins the item at price v1 then the output (p,x) is p = v1and x = (1, Ø, Ø, ..., Ø) buyer 1 doesn’t prefer any other’s allocation Ø any other buyer doesn’t prefer buyer 1’s allocation 5

  6. Envy-Freeness Given an output (p,x), the utility of buyer i is defined to be vij – pj, if i wins item j 0, if i wins nothing An output (p,x) is envy-free if the utility of every buyer is maximized at the corresponding allocation for the given price vector. That is, if i wins item j, vij – pj ≥ 0; and for any other item k, vij – pj ≥ vik – pk if i wins nothing, for any other item k, 0 ≥ vik – pk 6

  7. Example Not envy-free! $2 $5 $3 $2 $6 $3 $4 $5 $4 Does an envy-free solution always exist for any instance? $8 7

  8. Competitive Equilibrium An output (x,p) is called a competitive equilibrium if (market clearance) item priced at 0 if not allocated out items of non-zero price are all sold out (fairness) all buyers are envy-free Does a competitive equilibrium exist? 8

  9. Example $2 $5 $0 $5 $6 $3 $0 $6 $4 $8 9

  10. Computation of Competitive Equilibrium Theorem 10.1 (Shapley & Shubik). A competitive equilibrium always exists. How can we find one? 10

  11. Computation – Demand Graph Given a price vector p, create a bipartite graph G(p) = (A,B;E), called demand graph, where Ais the set of buyers, B is the set of items (i,j) is an edge if vij – pj > 0 (i.e., i obtains positive utility from j) vij – pjis maximized among all items For every buyer i, its neighbor set is N(i) = {j: (i,j) ∈ E} items desired by i buyer’s most satisfied items at the current price vector 11

  12. Computation – Price Increment Given a price vector p and demand graph G(p) = (A,B;E) N(i) is the set of items that i desires (i.e., utility-maximized) If there is S ⊆ A s.t. |S| > |T| where T = N(S) there is no way to allocated items in T to buyers in S to satisfy everyone in S T is over-demanded increase prices of items in T to reduce its “over-demand” Which over-demanded items should be increased? 12

  13. Computation – Minimal Over-Demand Items Given a price vector p and demand graph G(p) = (A,B;E) we say a subset of items T ⊆ B is over-demanded if |S| > |T|, where S = {i ∈ A | N(i) ≠ Ø and N(i) ⊆ T} a subset of items T ⊆ B is minimal over-demanded if it is over-demanded and does not contain any over-demanded proper subset 13

  14. Example over-demanded, but not minimal $2 $5 $0 $6 $3 $0 $4 $8 minimal over-demanded 14

  15. Computation – Outline of the Algorithm Let p = 0 and initialize demand graph G(p) While there is an over-demanded subset price-increment: simultaneously increase current price vector p for the items in the minimal over-demanded subset till someone is about to change its demand set update the demand graph G(p) Output price vector: the final prices allocation vector: compute a matching of max size in G(p) 15

  16. Computation – Step 2 Price Increment Let T⊆B be a minimal over-demanded set and S = N(T) Raise pj for each jT by the same amount till one of the following events occurs There are iS and jT s.t. i obtains the max utility from j (i,j) becomes a new edge of G There are iS and jT s.t. (i,j)E and vij = pj max obtainable utility of i (from all items) is 0 delete node i 16

  17. value = (20,10) value = (80,40) value = (100,50) Example • Three buyers {R, B, G} • Two items {a, b} • Valuation vector: • R: (100, 50) • B: (80, 40) • G: (20, 10) a b 17

  18. value = (20,10) value = (80,40) value = (100,50) Initialization: Price p = 0 • Price vector: (0, 0) • Utility vector: • R: (100, 50) • B: (80, 40) • G: (20, 10) p1 = 0 p2 = 0 18

  19. value = (20,10) value = (80,40) value = (100,50) Initialization – Demand Graph • Price vector: (0, 0) • Utility vector: • R: (100, 50) • B: (80, 40) • G: (20, 10) • Minimal over-demanded subset: {a} p1 = 0 p2 = 0 19

  20. value = (20,10) value = (80,40) value = (100,50) While loop1: Increase Price • Price vector: (10, 0) • Utility vector: • R: (90, 50) • B: (70, 40) • G: (10, 10) p1 = 10 p2 = 0 20

  21. value = (20,10) value = (80,40) value = (100,50) While loop1: Update Graph • Price vector: (10, 0) • Utility vector: • R: (90, 50) • B: (70, 40) • G: (10, 10) • Minimal over-demanded subset: {a} p1 = 10 p2 = 0 21

  22. value = (20,10) value = (80,40) value = (100,50) While loop2: Increase Price • Price vector: (40, 0) • Utility vector: • R: (60, 50) • B: (40, 40) • G: (0, 10) p1 = 40 p2 = 0 22

  23. value = (20,10) value = (80,40) value = (100,50) While loop2: Update Graph • Price vector: (40, 0) • Utility vector: • R: (60, 50) • B: (40, 40) • G: (0, 10) • Minimal over-demandedsubset: {a, b} p1 = 40 p2 = 0 23

  24. value = (20,10) value = (80,40) value = (100,50) While loop3: Increase Price • Price vector: (50, 10) • Utility vector: • R: (50, 40) • B: (30, 30) • G: (0, 0) p1 = 50 p2 = 10 24

  25. value = (20,10) value = (80,40) value = (100,50) While loop3: Update Graph • Price vector: (50, 10) • Utility vector: • R: (50, 40) • B: (30, 30) • G: (0, 0) • No over-demanded items! p1 = 50 p2 = 10 25

  26. value = (20,10) value = (80,40) value = (100,50) Final Output • Price vector: (50, 10) • Allocation vector: (a, b, Ø) p1 = 50 p2 = 10 26

  27. Example $2 $5 $0 $2 $1 $6 $3 $0 $4 $3 $2 $5 $1 $4 $8 minimal over-demanded 27

  28. Computation of Competitive Equilibrium Theorem 10.2 (Demange, Gale, Sotomayor). The above “ascending auction” algorithm computes a competitive equilibrium. 28

  29. Properties of Competitive Equilibrium Given an allocation x, the social welfare is defined to be f(x) = ∑i vi,x(i) That is, the total valuations obtained for all buyers. An allocation x is called efficient if for any other feasible allocation x’, f(x) ≥ f’(x). 29

  30. Properties of Competitive Equilibrium First Fundamental Welfare Theorem. For any competitive equilibrium (p,x), the allocation x is efficient, i.e., it maximizes social welfare. Second Fundamental Welfare Theorem. For any efficient allocation x, there is a price vector p such that (p,x) is a competitive equilibrium. 30

  31. Stability and Competitive Equilibrium What is the relation between competitive equilibrium and stability? Definition of preferences: buyers prefer items with larger utility (i.e., vij – pj) sellers (i.e., items) prefer buyers with larger payment 31

  32. Stability in Multi-Item Market Given an outcome (p,x), where pj is the price of item j (i.e., the total payment that seller j receives) xi is the allocation of buyer we say (i,j) a blocking pair if there is p’j such that p’j > pj(i.e., item j can receive more payment) the utility that i obtains in (p,x) is less than vij – p’j(i.e., by payment p’j to item j buyer i can get more utility) An outcome (p,x) is stable if it has no blocking pairs j new utility i old utility i new utility j old utility 32

  33. Stability and Competitive Equilibrium Theorem 10.2 (Shapley, Shubik) In a multi-item market, an outcome (p,x) is a competitive equilibrium if and only if it is stable. Proof. If (p,x) is a competitive equilibrium, consider any buyer i: If xi = j (i.e., i wins item j), then and for any item k, vij – pj ≥ vik – pk. Hence, for any p’k > pk, vij – pj ≥ vik – pk > vik – p’k If xi =Ø (i.e., i wins nothing), for any item k, 0 ≥ vik – pk. Hence, for any p’k > pk, 0 ≥ vik – pk> vik – p’k That is, i and k cannot be a blocking pair, i.e., (p,x) is stable 33

  34. Stability and Competitive Equilibrium Proof (continue). If (p,x) is stable, consider any buyer i: If xi = j (i.e., i wins item j), for any item k, if vij – pj < vik – pk then there is p’k > pk such that vij – pj < vik – p’k < vik – pk That is, (i, k) is a blocking pair, a contradiction. If xi =Ø (i.e., i wins nothing), for any item k, if0 < vik – pkHence, for any p’k > pk, 0 < vik – p’k< vik – pk Again, (i, k) is a blocking pair, a contradiction. That is, everyone is satisfied with his allocation, i.e., (p,x) is a competitive equilibrium 34

  35. Stability and Competitive Equilibrium Since stability = competitive equilibrium, do other properties of stability, e.g., men/women optimal stable matching linear program and lattice structure one side truthfulness apply to competitive equilibrium? 35

  36. Lattice Structure Given two competitive equilibria (p,x) and (p’,x’), we say (p,x) ≤ (p’,x’) if for all items, we have pj ≤ p’j Theorem 10.3 (Shapley, Shubik) The partial order ≤ forms a complete lattice. (p1,x1) (p2,x2) (p3,x3) (p4,x4) 36

  37. Minimum/Maximum Competitive Equilibrium An outcome (p,x) is called a minimum competitive equilibrium if it is a competitive equilibrium and for any other competitive equilibrium (p’,x’), we have pj ≤ p’jfor all items. represents the interests of all buyers in terms of their total payment. maximum competitive equilibrium if it is a competitive equilibrium and for any other competitive equilibrium (p’,x’), we have pj ≥ p’jfor all items. represents the interests of all items (i.e., sellers) in terms of total payment received 37

  38. Properties of Min/Max Competitive Equilibrium Existence. Lattice theorem implies that both minimum and maximum equilibria always exist. Uniqueness. A min/max competitive equilibrium may NOT be unique. For example, two buyers and one item with v1 = v2 = 10, there are two min/max competitive equilibria: p=10, x=(1,Ø) and p=10, x=(Ø,1). However, the price vector in min/max equilibrium is unique. 38

  39. Properties of Min/Max Competitive Equilibrium Connection to first/second price auction. When there is a single item, what are min/max competitive equilibria? min equilibrium = 2nd price auction = buyer-optimal max equilibrium = 1st price auction = seller-optimal 39

  40. Properties of Min/Max Competitive Equilibrium Computation. How can we compute a min/max competitive equilibrium? (Demange, Gale, Sotomayor) ascending auction algorithm computes a min competitive equilibrium computation of max equilibrium 40

  41. Properties of Min/Max Competitive Equilibrium One-side truthfulness. What if (vij) are private information and buyer i bid (bij) strategically for every item j? min competitive equilibrium mechanism: it is a dominant strategy for every buyer to report his true valuation (vij) max competitive equilibrium mechanism: it is possible that some buyer bid a false value to obtain more utility 41

More Related