1 / 47

Education and Wages

Education and Wages. Pedro Telhado Pereira May 2004 Part 3. We have arrived in part 1 to the following formula – at the time the individual finish his studies. But the wage profile is. Mincer (1974) suggested.

tuyen
Download Presentation

Education and Wages

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Education and Wages Pedro Telhado Pereira May 2004 Part 3

  2. We have arrived in part 1 to the following formula – at the time the individual finish his studies

  3. But the wage profile is

  4. Mincer (1974) suggested • Individuals at time t will devote a certain percentage of his time to acquire human capital – ht

  5. And therefore

  6. The equation we estimate is Where: x – is the work experience after school – generally age-years of education – age of start of education X – other variables r - rate of return of Education To be correct the wage should be a % as individuals are devoting part of their time to acquire human capital.

  7. Problems with the estimation of the equation • Problem 1 - Endogeneity of Education • Assume that an individual chooses education and maximises a utility function of the type: subject to the individual’s opportunity set summarised by w=g(E),

  8. The first order condition for optimal education requires that: For the sake of simplicity, it is assumed that the marginal costs are increasing functions of the amount invested in education, and that the marginal returns do not vary with education (the latter assumption is only a matter of simplicity and can be discarded without changing the main implication)

  9. Since the individual invests in education until the point where marginal costs equal marginal benefits, his optimal amount of education is given by:

  10. Integration of the marginal benefits leads to a log-linear wage equation for individual i of the type:

  11. The model identifies two sources of heterogeneity in the population: variation in marginal rates of return to education at each level of schooling (loosely known as differences in ability) and variation in the marginal costs of investment in schooling (loosely known as differences in access to funds or tastes for education).

  12. The general econometric problem

  13. We have to use instrumental variables • Z – instrumental variables Z must be correlated with X and is a full rank matrix and

  14. Instruments used (Harmon, Walker and Westergaard-Nielsen (2001)): • Variation of Compulsory school law • Month of birth • Years of war – Vietnam, II WW • Distance to college • Family variables • Abolition of fees • Age (Barceinas, Oliver, Raymond and Roig(2001))

  15. In Barceinas, Oliver, Raymond and Roig(2001) paper • “… in the Spanish case the ability bias seems to be not very important and that differences between the OLS and IV estimates do not follow a clearly identifiable pattern…”

  16. The common finding of the literature • The IV estimates are higher than the OLS estimates – Card 1999. • Possible explanation: IV estimators do not represent sample average returns to education but the marginal returns to education of certain subgroups of the population.

  17. The use of fixed effects to handle ability • The problem is that we can not observe a individual with and without education simultaneously as most individuals don’t get more education after they start working. • Use of data on twins (or family members) – the IV estimates are higher than the OLS estimates.

  18. Problem 2 - The return by level of education in Portugal

  19. There is not a constant return to education - it depends on the level of education • Similar results were obtained using Spanish data (Barceinas-Paredes, F., J. Oliver-Afonso, J. L. Raymond-Bara, J. L. Roig-Sabaté (2001))

  20. Problem 3 - The OLS assumes a paralel shifting of the distribution W0 Wed

  21. If there is not a paralel shift • “there may be information gains from estimating and comparing several conditional location measures for the dependent variable, even after controlling for a large set of observed individual and job characteristics” (Hartog, Pereira and Vieira,1999) .

  22. Rates of return to education (%)

  23. This result appears for other european countries and the USA.

  24. Results for European Countries - Martins and Pereira (2004)

  25. In a graph

  26. The highest rate is in Portugal – 12.6% • The lowest one is Sweden – 4.1% • The value for Spain is 8.6%

  27. In the majority of countries we observe • The return is higher in the top decile than it is at the lower decile.

  28. Can we say that Portugal has a high rate of return to Education? • We should take, at least, two points in consideration • Support from the State to the Families • Risk of the investment

  29. In Asplund and Pereira (1999) we showed that there is a negative relationship between State Support and Returns to Education

  30. In Pereira and Martins (2002), we showed that there is a negative relationship between return and risk as in all assets.

  31. We used the difference between the coefficient of education at the last decile and the first decile[1] as the measure of the risk [1] The significance of the difference was tested for several countries and it showed to be significantly different from zero, provided the sample was large enough.

  32. we construct dummy variables for years (yeari=1 if year=i, zero otherwise), type of wage (net=1, if net wages were used, zero otherwise). dif stands for the difference in returns between the last and first decile, absdif for its absolute value and ols for the OLS Mincer equation coefficient corrected.

  33. The main finding is the positive relationship between return and risk. There seems to be a positive compensation to “be received” to face the risk of the investment in education.

  34. And what about signalling? • Workers acquire costly education in order to signal their higher ability to employers – who would otherwise know little about their prospective workers skills . Education per se plays no role in enhancing a worker’s productivity and is almost entirely wasteful from the public or social point of view. • One way to test this idea involves comparing the returns to education between employees and the self-employed. The intuition behind this results is whereas the former may benefit from education as a signal, the others will not, given that they are their own employers and have no informational asymmetries problems to deal with. The results for Portugal suggest that returns to education for the self-employed are at least as high as those for employees, therefore there is no sign of signalling.

  35. Barceinas-Paredes, F., J. Oliver-Afonso, J. L. Raymond-Bara, J. L. Roig-Sabaté and A. Skalli (2001) • Use Spanish and French Data • Use • Private and Public Sector • Public sector is more prone to signalling • No evidence for the screening hypothesis • Number of years of education and relative position in attainment • Years=Human Capital, relative position=screening • Education is likely to serve as a signalling device but only to a rather limited extent.

  36. Experience eearnings profile of higly educated individuals • More tenure = less signalling • None of the predictions of the screening hypothesis could be strongly confirmed • Sheepskin effects • More years to attain a degree less signal • Even if the results show that there are many (human capital) reasons to obtain the same result

  37. Their conclusions: • “…our results suggest unanimously that the effect of education is primarily due to its impact in individual’ productivity…” • “… our findings confirm the idea that although there might be some elements of truth in the screening hypothesis, the returns to education are to the greatest extent due to human capital accumulation…”

  38. References • Asplund, R. and P. T. Pereira . (1999), ‘Introduction’, in (eds), Returns to human capital in Europe: a literature review, Helsinki, Finland: ETLA/Taloustieto Oy., pp 259-278. • Barceinas-Paredes, F., J. Oliver-Afonso, J. L. Raymond-Bara, J. L. Roig-Sabaté and A. Skalli (2001), Does Education Improve Productivity or Earnings Only, in: R. Asplund,eds, Education and Earnings – Further Evidence from Europe, ETLA, Helsinki. • Barceinas-Paredes, F., J. Oliver-Afonso, J. L. Raymond-Bara, J. L. Roig-Sabaté (2001), Spain, in: C. Harmon, I. Walker and N. W. Nielsen, eds, Education and Earnings in Europe – a Cross Country Analysis of Returns to Education, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. • Bosworth, D., P. Dawkins and T. Stromback (1996), The Economics of the Labour Market, Longman, Singapore. • Card, D. (1999), The Causal Impact of Education on Earnings, in: O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, eds, Handbook of Labor Economics, North Holland, Amsterdam and New York. • Harmon C., I. Walker and N. W. Nielsen, (2001), Introduction, in: C. Harmon, I. Walker and N. W. Nielsen, eds, Education and Earnings in Europe – a Cross Country Analysis of Returns to Education, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. • Hartog, J., P.T. Pereira, J. C. Vieira (1999) "Changing Returns to Education in Portugal During the 1980s and Early 1990s: OLS and Quantile Regression Analysis", Applied Economics, 33/8, 2001, 1021-1037. • Martins, P.S. and P.T. Pereira (2004) "Does Education Reduce Wage Inequality? Quantile Regressions Evidence from Fifteen European Countries and the USA" (forthcoming Labour Economics. • Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, Experience and Earnings. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research. • Pereira, P. T. and P. S. Martins (2001), Portugal, in: C. Harmon, I. Walker and N. W. Nielsen, eds, Education and Earnings in Europe – a Cross Country Analysis of Returns to Education, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. • Pereira, P. T. and P. S. Martins (2002), "Is there a Return-Risk Link in Education", Economic Letters, 75, 31-37, (2002).

More Related