1 / 16

Conjectural variations: unilateral effects

This article discusses the incorporation of rival responses into simplified unilateral effects measures, with a focus on the Generalised Pricing Pressure Index (GePP). It explores the authorities' use of price pressure tests and provides intuitive implications of GePP. The article also examines the policy implications of these measures.

wjackson
Download Presentation

Conjectural variations: unilateral effects

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Conjectural variations: unilateral effects Incorporating rival responses into simplified unilateral effects measures • Adrian Majumdar & Chris Doyle • adrian.majumdar@rbbecon.comchris.doyle@rbbecon.com

  2. Overview • Authorities’ use of price pressure tests • Theoretical approach to integrating rival responses into UPP: GePP • Applying GePP in practice • Formal implementation • Informal implementation • Intuitive implications of GePP • Policy implications

  3. Authorities’ Use of Price Pressure Tests • Recognition that market share based screens can be poor indicators of harm in differentiated goods markets (Werden 1996, Shapiro 1996) CC • Somerfield Morrisons, 2005 (symmetric IPR) • Zipcar /Streecar, 2011 (GUPPI) OFT • Lovefilm/Amazon (rebuttable presumption of SLC arising from high D and high M) • [NB. Rebuttable presumption no longer applies] • Asda/Netto, 2010 (IPR, isoelastic, asymmetric diversion ratio, efficiencies) • Unilever/ Alberto Culver, 2011 (GUPPI with multi products, upstream market) • These days GUPPI is more likely to be considered than IPR?

  4. Upwards pricing pressure (UPP) • A first order approach to calculating the impact of a merger on price • UPP on product 1 = D12 (P2 – C2) – EC1 • Standard approach – internalisation of demand spill-over to firm 2 • Opportunity cost (cannibalisation) intuition of Farrell & Shapiro • Weighed up against efficiency gain (reduction in marginal cost) • Can then think about pass through of higher cannibalisation cost

  5. GUPPI = Gross Upward Pricing Pressure Index • GUPPI for product 1 D12 * (P2 – C2) P1 • Perceived increase in marginal cost of selling another unit, as a percentage of price • Intuition: post merger, the owner of product 1 faces a perceived increase in cost, if the cost increase is a high share of the price of product 1, then pass through (higher prices) are more likely. • Can multiply GUPPI by pass through rate to obtain “first order” estimate of price increase caused by a merger.

  6. “Illustrative” price rises with symmetric demand and cost What is a price pressure test? • Merger simulation? • A way to put information on percentage margins and diversion ratios in context? • Screen: IPR > 5% or GUPPI > 10% => worth looking further? (Retail mergers with many local overlaps.) • Evidence weighed up with other factors.

  7. Judging a price pressure test • Lucid (understood by policy makers) • Implementable at Phase I (data, time) • Predictive power (good or bad?!) • Example: • Do “equilibrium properties” of IPRs trump First Order Approach to Mergers (FOAM)? • Not if FOAM offers a better LIP service… • Both are approximations anyway (e.g. ignore supply side responses) • The research question: given an environment where the OFT uses price pressure tests, should such tests be updated to include pricing conjectures?

  8. Jaffe and Weyl – Generalised Pricing Pressure (GePP) • Extend UPP to incorporate rival responses using conjectural variations • A complex theoretical model which covers a range of issues • We aim to simplify and present the main intuitive implications for policy • Adding greater realism should act towards better predictive power… • But is GePP implementable and clear to policy makers?

  9. GePP: incorporating CVs requires a conjectured diversion ratio • Conventional UPP uses the standard diversion ratio which holds rivals’ prices constant following a price increase by firm 1 • Jaffe and Weyl consider the implications of rival responses for diversion patterns, and how this affects incentives to change price in the first place • In particular they consider firms as having “accommodating” pricing reactions • Post merger, firm 1 also considers how rivals will respond but treats firm 2’s price as fixed

  10. GePP: incorporating CVs requires a modified diversion ratio • This “conjectured” diversion ratio is different from the standard one in 2 ways: • Fewer customers will be lost by firm 1 as a result of a price increase, as accommodating rivals will be more expensive • More customers will be recaptured at firm 2 as a result of the price increase by firm 1, as firm 2 will now be relatively cheaper than accommodating rivals • Therefore with accommodating reactions the conjectured diversion ratio is greater than the standard one – indicating the potential for greater price increases than with standard UPP

  11. GePP: end of accommodating reactions • Jaffe and Weyl highlight that a consideration of rival responses introduces a new effect - the merger will lead to the “end of accommodating reactions” (EAR) • Pre-merger the fact that an increase in firm 1’s price would lead to an increase in the price of firm 2 would have encouraged higher pricing by firm 1 • Post merger the price of product 2 is directly controlled by firm 1, so this indirect incentive to increase price is removed • Indicates the potential for smaller prices increases than with UPP • Broad intuition: if 1 and 2 were accommodating each other pre-merger, there is less competition to be “lost” as a result of the merger • Overall 2 opposing effects: conjectured diversion vs. EAR

  12. Implementing GePP formally • By assuming consistent conjectures GePP can potentially be formally estimated using data obtained from cost shocks • However this is potentially (very) complex: • Clean cost shocks to the merging parties • Sufficient data to allow us to accurately observe their impact • Econometric approaches required to estimate GePP using this data • Given the time and data constraints faced during the screening phase for mergers, unlikely that this formal approach will be practically implementable • Simplified versions of GePP outlined by Jaffe & Weyl may be more implementable – but they appear to be based on strong assumptions (as are IPRs)

  13. Implementing GePP informally • Sometimes measures used to imply diversion ratios may in some senses already incorporate the reactions of rivals (e.g. internal business documents) • Notable exception is surveys which potentially measure the standard diversion ratio • Rather than being a problem, Jaffe & Weyl claim this may be an advantage as GePP emphasises that we actually want a measure that incorporates rival responses • Though note this information will only be a rough approximation as it typically will not hold the price of product 2 constant as desired • BUT don’t just plug this diversion ratio into a standard UPP formula, as this will ignore the EAR term and could therefore bias the outcome • Don’t mix and match models: implement GePP fully or stick to UPP • But it may be difficult to estimate EAR here

  14. Intuitive implications of GePP • Even if GePP can’t be properly implemented, it may provide an indication of when standard UPP over- or understates true upwards pricing pressure • Example: NBTY/Julian Graves • 2 major specialist retailers of nuts seeds and dried fruit • Key question is the role of supermarkets in providing a competitive constraint • Evidence indicated supermarkets did not monitor the parties’ pricing • Implies zero conjectures, meaning conjectured DR equals the conventional DR • But EAR is likely to be present (parties monitored each other) • This indicates that UPP here likely overstates upwards pricing pressure

  15. Policy Implications • GePP may potentially provide a way to take into account rivals’ reactions in an upwards pricing pressure measure • However,this approach will usually not be (properly) implementable at Phase I • Nevertheless, GePP indicates that if we ignore conjectures and undertake standard UPP, no obvious bias is introduced into merger control (benchmarked against a standard UPP screen) • Parties may not volunteer to the OFT that they accommodate each other! • But why wouldn’t the merger change conjectures? • Perhaps we shouldn’t try to pack too much into a single model

  16. Locations and contact • London Brussels • The Connection Bastion Tower198 High Holborn Place du Champ de Mars 5 London WC1V 7BD B–1050 Brussels Telephone +44 20 7421 2410 Telephone: +32 2 792 0000 Email: london@rbbecon.com Email: brussels@rbbecon.com • The Hague Melbourne • Lange Houtstraat 37-39 Rialto South Tower, Level 272511 CV  Den Haag 525 Collins StreetThe Netherlands Melbourne VIC 3000 Telephone: +31 70 302 3060 Telephone: +61 3 9935 2800Email: thehague@rbbecon.com Email: melbourne@rbbecon.com • Johannesburg • Augusta House, Inanda Greens54 Wierda Road WestSandton, 2196, JohannesburgTelephone: +27 11 783 1949Email: johannesburg@rbbecon.com

More Related