250 likes | 556 Views
Best Practices in Preventing and Monitoring Systemic Risk . July 9, 2009. The Bank of Korea Ilhwan Kim. Introduction. Ⅰ. Business activities of non-bank financial institutions, and the policy authorities' measures in response. Ⅱ. Some pointers and best practice. Ⅲ. Contents.
E N D
Best Practices in Preventing and Monitoring Systemic Risk July 9, 2009 The Bank of Korea Ilhwan Kim
Introduction Ⅰ Business activities of non-bank financial institutions, and the policy authorities' measures in response. Ⅱ Some pointers and best practice Ⅲ Contents
Ⅰ. Introduction • Among the causes of the recent global financial crisis, we may single out the lax regulation of hedge funds and large unregulated non-bank financial institutions (hereafter 'NFIs'). • In Korea, only a few hedge funds have a domestic market presence and their way of doing business has had little influence on the financial market. • Things have not yet reached such a pitch as to give cause for concern. • Recently, the「Capital Market and Investment Services Act」came into effect. • It provided a platform for the introduction of hedge funds.
Ⅰ. Introduction • It put in place a legal foundation for setting ceilings on derivatives investment and borrowing of money. • We had experience of system risk arising owing to the relatively more relaxed regulatory regime applied to large NFIs. • Examine the systemic risk generated by the reckless way in which merchant banking corporations (hereafter 'MBCs') and credit card companies (hereafter 'CCCs') operated in Korea. • Look at the measures adopted bythe policy authorities in response. • Draw on it in order to consider best practices in preventing and monitoring systemic risk arising from large NFIs rather than hedge funds.
Ⅱ. Business activities of non-bank financial institutions, and the policy authorities' measures in response. 1. Merchant Banking Corporations • MBCs, as the highly-leveraged non-banking financial institutions in Korea before the 1997 currency crisis, had carried out businesses similar to those of banks. • MBCs' business : Discounting commercial paper, Medium and long-term lending, Leasing, Securities brokerage, International financing, and Factoring. • MBCs are believed to have triggered the currency crisis, due to the following factors; • Severe maturity mismatches
1. Merchant Banking Corporations • MBCs Borrowed short-term capital at high interest rates in the international financial markets, and used the funds to extend long-term credit or invest in illiquid bonds in emerging markets. • This resulted in severe maturity mismatches between their foreign currency liabilities and assets. • In these circumstances, MBCs had troubles in short-term foreign currency borrowing and roll-overs due to the worsening international financial market conditions. • Following defaults on EME bonds in which they had invested, they faced foreign currency liquidity shortages.
1. Merchant Banking Corporations • Expansion of their domestic business scopes into more risky areas. • Despite lacking credit rating and analysis abilities, MBCs had extended non-secured loans to corporations with low credit ratings, by discounting CP. • As a result, MBC asset soundness was much aggravated due to the defaults of such corporations from 1997. • As MBCs started to withdraw their loans from faltering firms in response, a vicious spiral of accelerating firm bankruptcies and increasing MBC weakness occurred.
1. Merchant Banking Corporations • The loosening of regulations also triggered the currency crisis in some sense, causing MBCs' deterioration. • Financial supervisory and regulatory frame not systemically established • Although the policy authorities had the right to regulate the MBCs, it had no infrastructure for supervision such as supervisory experts and organizations. • Their function in systemic and comprehensive coordination of MBCs supervision turned out to be weak.
1. Merchant Banking Corporations • Negligent MBC business activity regulation • For the purpose of easing regulation of financial institutions, the new market entry of MBCs was allowed without any setting of required principles. • To attract foreign capital, establishment of new MBCs and conversion of all the existing investment finance companies into MBCs were allowed. • The rapid increase in number of MBCs caused excessive competition and lowering of business quality. • The government ignored the MBCs' herd behavior, such as crowded establishment of overseas branches. • This led to reckless foreign currency borrowing, increased funding costs and unsound asset management.
1. Merchant Banking Corporations • Insufficient regulation • The capital adequacy regulatory system was underdeveloped. • Before the currency crisis, the government regulated MBCs by means of a naive financial gearing ratio standard. • MBCs conducted careless asset management without considering the related risks. • The regulations on MBC credit concentration were loosened. • The permitted ceiling on MBC credit to conglomerates was three times that for commercial banks. • Loans and leases made to 'dispersed ownership companies' were excluded from ceiling calculation.
1. Merchant Banking Corporations • Although MBCs' loans, mostly unsecured, should have been more strictly regulated than those of banks, they were relatively loosely regulated. • As a result, the troubles at MBCs worsened rapidly. • There were imbalances between the regulations on MBCs' short-term and their long-term foreign currency borrowings. • In cases of medium and long-term (over 1-year maturity) foreign currency borrowing, MBCs were required to declare the transactions to the government. • For transaction amounts more than 10 million US dollars, they had to notify the government beforehand. • Short-term (less than 1-year maturity) borrowings were not only unrestricted but also excluded from the application of ceiling on total short-term borrowings. • MBCs enormously expanded their short-term borrowings which were more risky.
1. Merchant Banking Corporations • Overseas securities investment was unregulated. • The ceiling on investment in local securities had been regulated. • However, investment in overseas securities, had been excluded from application of the ceiling. • Without making any provision for risk, MBCs had continued to borrow short-term foreign currency and invest it in emerging-market bonds. • There were characterized by high risk and low liquidity. • The policy authorities worked to overcome the financial turmoil through restructuring, such as forcing the market exits or M&As of bad MBCs. • Only two MBCs are currently in business in Korea and their scope of business reduced. • They are regulated in accordance with the same criteria as banks.
2. Credit card companies • After the 1997 currency crisis, the number of CCCs increased substantially. • The reasons were • the growth of retail financing thanks to the rapid domestic economic recovery and continuing low interest rate level, and • the belief that credit card market would achieve higher returns. • In particular, certain measures by the policy authorities', including a tax deduction, elimination of both the administrative ceiling on monthly cash advances and the leverage limit on credit card issuers, and application of relatively light capital adequacy ratio, contributed to a boom.
2. Credit card companies • From 1999 to 2002, the number of credit cards in use tripled, while the volume of total credit card transactions expanded sevenfold. • During the same period, the total assets of CCCs also rose more than fivefold. • These institutional support and financial deregulation resulted in the generation of a credit card bubble. • Fierce competition for market share between CCCs, caused by the easing of market entry regulations, led to a relaxation of lending standards and risk management. • The limited infrastructure for reporting and sharing of credit information led to insufficient evaluation and investigation of the credit conditions of card applicants.
2. Credit card companies • Credit cards were excessively issued even to households with low credit and they were given credit limits beyond their repayment capacities. • CCCs ignored the importance of risk management. On the contrary, they concentrated their efforts on high-risk, high-return areas of businesses including card loans and cash advances. • Herd behavior appeared in the credit market, as some CCCs focused on expansionary strategies and others followed the same strategy to avoid losing their market share.
2. Credit card companies • The credit card bubble burst in 2003, so the financial conditions of CCCs deteriorated dramatically. • The volume of delinquent card loans rose sharply due to the lowered debt-servicing capacity of households. • CCCs became more cautious in issuing new credit cards and making card loans, and carried out follow-up measures including calling in of loans to lower-rated borrowers, prohibition of balance transfers, and reductions of loan ceilings. • Household and credit company soundness deteriorated further with the soaring volume of delinquent loans and appearance of a credit crunch.
2. Credit card companies • To prevent the deterioration at CCCs from spreading to systemic risk, the policy authorities took the measures. • They upgraded credit card asset classification standards, strengthened loan loss provisioning requirements and began to apply Prompt Corrective Action measures. • They raised the minimum capital adequacy ratio for card issuers, from 7 percent to 8 percent. • They also banned aggressive street marketing practices and established a cap on cash advances of less than 50 percent of total CCC assets. • However, these measures did not calm market participants' unrest as expected, but led to a worsening credit crunch among CCCs.
2. Credit card companies • The policy authorities changed their tactics to more active intervention. • They provided a large volume of liquidity to support troubled CCCs and thus enhance financial market stability. • They pressured CCCs to undertake self-rescue efforts and to take some measures to improve their balance sheet conditions, including injections of capital by their majority shareholders. • They allowed CCCs to roll over their delinquent credit card loans by exercising de facto regulatory forbearance on ancillary business ratio regulations.
2. Credit card companies • They made the conditions necessary for exercising Prompt Corrective Action more realistic and helped CCCs repay or dispose of their delinquent loans. • To ease the liquidity crunch of CCCs and the money market distress, they also extended maturities of credit card receivables indefinitely. • The financial market returned to stability, on the back of expectations that the short-term liquidity problems of CCCs would be resolved.
Ⅲ. Some pointers and best practice • The irresponsible business models and ways of running operations of large unregulated NFIs may lead to systemic risk . • It can bring about heavy social costs in that the resulting financial market unrest can give rise to financial crisis or financial panic. • In the light of our experience related to systemic risk arising from large unregulated NFIs’ deterioration in Korea, the following best practices can be considered.
Ⅲ. Some pointers and best practice • Construction and operation of internal control systems based on risk management • It is very important to bring about recognition of risk management. To this end, NFIs’ routine construction of risk management systems should be encouraged and a regime put in place to confirm compliance at regular intervals. • What is more, a risk management department should be set up as an independent organization, and reporting systems put in place that constantly report back to top managers. • In addition, stress tests analysis should be undertaken to guard against overly optimistic expectations as to the future management environment.
Ⅲ. Some pointers and best practice • Strengthening of prudential supervision and regulation of NFIs’ soundness • A risk-based supervisory framework should also be introduced and brought into operation for the NFIs like that for the bank. • NFIs that have been in a comparatively relaxed prudential supervisory and regulatory regime, should in future be subject to the same level of supervision as banks. • Heightening the transparency of NFIs’ management information • The scope for disclosure of NFIs' management information should be expanded, and accounting standards revised on a systematic basis.
Ⅲ. Some pointers and best practice • The information should be promptly made available to market participants. • Moreover, the financial supervisory authorities should disclose within a certain range the findings concerning NFIs’ evaluated in the course of on-site examination. • Imposing liability on the majority shareholder of NFIs • In order to avoid moral hazard on the part of market participants, the majority shareholders should bear the liability for failed NFIs. • A system should be established whereby majority shareholders of NFIs make up a considerable part of management losses.
Ⅲ. Some pointers and best practice • The policy authorities' direct intervention in order to safeguard the financial system stability by acting as an orchestrator. • If NFIs failed, the policy authorities should swiftly divide them into those that are systemically important and those that are not. • In order to prevent contagion effects, support for a turnaround can be given to those paths of systemically important through the supply of liquidity whereas the remaining institutions should exit the market.