410 likes | 701 Views
local public good and private good may / may not be perfect substitutes ... private incomes yi are exogenous. public goods produced from
E N D
1. MSc Public Economics 2008/9http://darp.lse.ac.uk/ec426 Fiscal Governance: Local Public Goods Aim of this lecture
Local public goods
How are jurisdictions determined?
Should there be public or private provision?
V103
http://darp.lse.ac.uk/presentations/ec426/FiscalAdministration.ppt
Leila: 6674
6300 (or 7437 or 6460). A31 Audio Visual Unit
DESMOND Mr George 6271 g.desmond@lse.ac.uk
FLOOD Mr Ray 7694 r.flood@lse.ac.uk
GALE Mr Adam 6520 a.gale@lse.ac.uk
HEAD Mr Chris 6417 c.head@lse.ac.uk
Aim of this lecture
Local public goods
How are jurisdictions determined?
Should there be public or private provision?
V103
http://darp.lse.ac.uk/presentations/ec426/FiscalAdministration.ppt
Leila: 6674
6300 (or 7437 or 6460). A31 Audio Visual Unit
DESMOND Mr George 6271 g.desmond@lse.ac.uk
FLOOD Mr Ray 7694 r.flood@lse.ac.uk
GALE Mr Adam 6520 a.gale@lse.ac.uk
HEAD Mr Chris 6417 c.head@lse.ac.uk
2. Overview...
3. Public goods and the public sector Public and semi-public goods provide a challenge
how to ensure efficient allocation
how to reveal willingness to pay
should they be provided in private or public sector?
There are some standard answers
only work for small communities?
special mechanisms
Here examine an alternative approach
redefine the problem
focus on the way people make choices…
what kind of fiscal environment do they want?
4. Tiebout’s intuition Up to now the economy as a whole has been fixed
no question of governance
nor of “jurisdiction” of the fiscal system
Introduce the possibility of multiple jurisdictions
affects basket of goods provided
zone in which it is possible to determine taxes
crucial point: relationship amongst jurisdictions
Tiebout (1956) virtually invented our topic
changed context of the public-goods argument
a new role for consumer choice: voting with your feet
made an analogy with a private market place
modern evidence that this choice mechanism works (Banzhaf and Walsh 2008) Tiebout:
“Just as the consumer may be visualised as walking to a private market place to buy his goods we place him in the position of walking to a community where the prices (taxes) of community services are set “Both trips take the consumer to the market. “ There is no way in which the consumer can avoid revealing his preferences in a spatial economy”
Banzhaf-Walsh: Using a locational equilibrium model, we derive formal tests of his premise. The model predicts increased population density in neighborhoods experiencing exogenous improvements in public goods and, for large improvements, increased relative mean incomes. We test these hypotheses in the context of changing air quality. Our results provide strong empirical support for the notion that households “vote with their feet” for environmental quality.Tiebout:
“Just as the consumer may be visualised as walking to a private market place to buy his goods we place him in the position of walking to a community where the prices (taxes) of community services are set “Both trips take the consumer to the market. “ There is no way in which the consumer can avoid revealing his preferences in a spatial economy”
Banzhaf-Walsh: Using a locational equilibrium model, we derive formal tests of his premise. The model predicts increased population density in neighborhoods experiencing exogenous improvements in public goods and, for large improvements, increased relative mean incomes. We test these hypotheses in the context of changing air quality. Our results provide strong empirical support for the notion that households “vote with their feet” for environmental quality.
5. Tiebout: questions What type of equilibrium?
Depends upon the exact specification of the mechanism that is supposed to be operating
How are communities determined?
Equilibrium concepts that take into account the endogenous structure of communities
How does the economy work out of equilibrium?
Tiebout suggested a migration mechanism
Will there be an efficient outcome from the Tiebout process?
Is this more than just a demand-revealing mechanism?
6. Overview...
7. Endogenous structure The endogeneity of the community gives a nice clue
Think of each community as privately determined
The public good issues remain within each community
But free choice between communities
This suggests an analogy with the theory of clubs
Originally developed by Buchanan (1965)
Combines public and private elements
See also Cornes and Sandler (1996)
8. Clubs: excludability and rivalness The good is like a public good within the club
Excludability: club good is restricted to its members
people can be excluded from membership
can charge a membership fee
membership entitles you to full consumption of the good without further charge
Rivalness: could we assume that club good is non-rival?
for realism, allow for the possibility of congestion
cost of providing the club good may rise with the membership
same may also be true of the marginal cost Exclusion:
no exclusion of individual services
no specialised “packages”
Exclusion:
no exclusion of individual services
no specialised “packages”
9. Clubs: model of production A two good economy
measure values in terms of private good
Notation:
x – amount of private good,
z – amount of club good,
s – size of the of club
C(z, s) – cost of producing the club good
Standard assumptions about cost:
Cz(z, s) > 0 – MC of club good is positive
Czz(z, s) ? 0 – MC of club good is nondecreasing in z
Cs(z, s) ? 0 – possibility of congestion
Examine this in an economy with fixed total output
equivalent to assuming a given amount of income y
10. Clubs: production possibilities This is the diagram for the economy as a wholeThis is the diagram for the economy as a whole
11. Clubs: individual optimisation Use this in a model of individual choice
Each individual has the utility function U(x, z)
Assume that club costs are divided equally: C(z, s) / s
so the budget constraint is:
x + C(z, s) / s = y
So the problem becomes: maximise
U(y ? C(z, s) / s , z)
Differentiate with respect to z:
1
? — Cz(z, s) Ux(x, z) + Uz(x, z) = 0
s
Differentiate with respect to s:
1
— [C(z, s) ? s Cs(z, s)] Ux(x, z) = 0
s2
12. Club model: individual’s equilibrium This is the diagram for the individual
This is the diagram for the individual
13. Clubs: basic results Optimal amount of club good must satisfy:
Uz(x, z)
Cz(z, s) = s ----
Ux(x, z)
MRT= S MRS
just as for public goods
The optimal membership must satisfy:
Cs(z, s) = C(z, s) / s
MC of providing services = Access cost
14. Clubs: summary Model is a simple extension of classic public goods
Novelty is to introduce a type of partial exclusion mechanism
In the standard case we get two easily interpreted marginalist rules:
On the level of provision of the club good
On the access conditions to the club
15. Overview...
16. Modelling local public goods Focus on a collection of communities
think of them as tax jurisdictions
each jurisdiction works a bit like a club
Affinity with the club model
an excludable non-rival good
no exclusion within the jurisdiction
local public good and private good may / may not be perfect substitutes
there may or may not be congestion
may also need to consider overall size of the “economy”
People choose jurisdiction in the same way they choose a club
have preferences over private, public goods
migration mechanism: vote with their feet
What would the outcome look like?
17. Stiglitz model of a community Assume simple linear technology
no congestion costs
MRT in community is set at 1
total output is given by Q = xs + z
Assume production depends on the size of the community:
Community subject to diminishing returns in population
Q = f (s)
f is an increasing concave function
Take tradeoff in (public,private)-space
For a given size of community this is linear
All public: (f (s), 0)
All private: (0, f (s) / s )
Consider the optimum for a given community size
18. Stiglitz model: single s
19. Stiglitz model: solution Previous diagram is a “short-run” model
Optimum determined in usual way
MRS = 1 / s
MRT = S MRS =1
However we ought to consider the possibility of multiple jurisdictions
Each one may differ in size
Overall production possibility determined as an envelope
20. Stiglitz model: multiple s
21. Stiglitz model: types of solution
22. Stiglitz model: questions Why the nonconvexity?
Follows from relationship between size and provision of goods
An artefact of special assumptions?
What if we used a conventional club-good model?
Introduce rising marginal cost again
Homogenous consumers?
Suppose people differ in their taste for public goods
Will the demand-revelation mechanism work?
Will an equilibrium always exist?
Deal with each of these in turn…
23. Modified model: multiple s
24. Heterogeneous citizens A simple example to illustrate the point:
three types of public goods
two types of citizen
Preferences are given by
citizen type 1: U(x, z1 + kz3) where 0 < ? < 1
citizen type 2: U(x, z2 + kz3)
If the two types are separated:
group i specialises in public good type i
If the two are together:
may be economies of scale in the production of good 3
particularly important if ? is close to 1
So free allocation via migration may not be efficient
analogous to the market failure of pure private goods where there is increasing returns Two of the goods are special to the two types; third good is common
Good 3 is attractive to both groups
But it is less attractive than good i to type i, i = 1, 2Two of the goods are special to the two types; third good is common
Good 3 is attractive to both groups
But it is less attractive than good i to type i, i = 1, 2
25. Equilibrium: the core Core: set of unblocked allocations
a fundamental solution concept for equilibrium
for private goods core is non-empty
any competitive equilibrium must lie in the core
Core of an economy with public goods
existence theorem does not necessarily apply
equilibrium mechanisms different
The core may be empty unless
equal sharing is enforced (Pauly 1970 )
all clubs are of uniform size (Pauly 1970 )
if individuals have the same tastes (Stiglitz 1977)
Need to examine nature of Tiebout equilibrium more closely
26. Overview...
27. Basic questions on equilibrium What type of choice?
Fixed number of jurisdictions?
Freely set up jurisdictions (prairie model)?
Fixed overall population
Single type of public good
What type of mechanism?
usually assume simple migration
people follow the money
Will equilibrium be efficient?
28. Local public goods: fixed number of communities Assume that there are just two communities
Overall size is given at N
s1 + s2 = N
Allow for free choice between communities
Two possibilities of equilibrium
(1) Where only one community is settled:
u(N) ? 0
(2) Where both communities are settled:
u(s1) = u(s2)
29. A model of social welfare Assume Benthamite objective function:
Per-person utility is same for everyone in a given community of size s: u(s)
Welfare is weighted sum of per-person utility in each community
W = s1u(s1) + s2u(s2)
= s1u(s1) + [N – s1] u(N – s1)
For an interior welfare maximum the optimal size where:
?W
—— = 0
? s1
which implies s1u'(s1) + u(s1) – [N – s1] u'(N – s1) – u(N – s1) = 0
But two complications
we also have to take account of corners
interior maximum may not be unique
Need to derive utility-possibility set from equilibrium conditions
30. 2-jurisdiction U-possibility (1)
31. 2-jurisdiction U-possibility (2)
32. 2-jurisdiction U-possibility (3)
33. Migration mechanism Will migration “work”?
yields stable equilibria?
yields efficient equilibria?
examine four cases
combined diagram facilitates interpretation
First case involves substantial economies of scale
Get multiple equilibria
Only extreme cases are stable
Only extreme cases are efficient
Second case also involves economies of scale
Only extreme cases are stable
Only interior case is efficient
Other cases show that multiple equilibria do not necessarily involve extremes
34. Pareto-efficient: extreme equilibria Involves substantial economies of scale
Get multiple equilibria
Only extreme cases are stable
Only extreme cases are efficient
Involves substantial economies of scale
Get multiple equilibria
Only extreme cases are stable
Only extreme cases are efficient
35. 3 Equilibria: inefficient extremes also involves economies of scale
Only extreme cases are stable
Only interior case is efficient
also involves economies of scale
Only extreme cases are stable
Only interior case is efficient
36. 3 interior eqa: efficient equality
37. 5 Equilibria: inefficient equality
38. Equilibria May be multiple equilibria
alternation between stable and unstable equilibria
two-community and single community equilibria may coexist
stable equilibria may be inefficient
An equilibrium is bound to exist if
if land values play no role
everyone is identical
the ?(·) functions are continuous
Where individuals differ, will equilibrium exist?
Need to examine specific models…
39. Overview...
40. Role of the state Should the provision of public goods be based on voluntarism, or coercion?
Local public goods models suggest more than one paradigm
With heterogeneous individuals there is a conflict of interests
Individuals will not agree on appropriate output and contributions:
They may be compelled to contribute at tax rates that seem to be unfair
Involuntary contributions:
can overcome the free-rider problem
do not resolve the conflict-of-interest problem
Voluntarism
avoids “unfairness” from compulsion
may not be consistent with the absence of free riding
Given the Tiebout adjustment mechanism, will one of these be eliminated?
41. An illustrative model To address “public or private?” question
construct a model of public good production
model two provision modes
allow Tiebout style choice between two modes
Utility of individual i
u(xi, z) = [xi1–s + z1–s] / [1 – s ]
private good xi public good z
s is nonnegative elasticity of substitution
Production
private incomes yi are exogenous
public goods produced from “contributions” of private good ci= yi – xi
MRT = 1, so amount of public good is: z = Si ci
Provision modes treated as two different models of a community… s = 0, total inflexibility
s = 8, perfect substitutess = 0, total inflexibility
s = 8, perfect substitutes
42. Two provision modes Coercive provision: public good provided by taxation
tax based on community aggregate income Y := Si yi
so i has to contribute ci = tY
tax rate t is selected by voting
chosen tax rate: t = [1 + [ymedian/Y]b]-1, b := [1 – s]/s
Voluntary provision: based on individual contributions
Like “conformity model” in tax compliance (Bergstrom et al 1986)
optimal contribution decision depends on income
ci = max {yi – Y / n*, 0}, n* := 1 + #{cj > 0} cannot be an individual income tax (would imply lump-sum taxation)
chosen tax rate based on what the median voter would select
Income ratio ymedian/Y decreases with greater inequality
t decreases with b: so it increases with sigma
t increases in inequality if s < 1 decreases in inequality if s > 1 cannot be an individual income tax (would imply lump-sum taxation)
chosen tax rate based on what the median voter would select
Income ratio ymedian/Y decreases with greater inequality
t decreases with b: so it increases with sigma
t increases in inequality if s < 1 decreases in inequality if s > 1
43. Provision: endogenous choice Suppose two communities exist simultaneously
people can “choose” public or private
use Tiebout model to address choice between communities
Three possible types of equilibrium:
all individuals migrate to the voluntary-provision community
all individuals migrate to the coercive-provision community
‘interior’ equilibria: collections of individuals in both communities
The relevant type depends on
degree of substitution (parameter s)
income distribution
? see Glomm and Lagunoff (1998)
44. Which mode of provision? Results for three types
Type 1: voluntary provision only
equilibrium always exists
Type 2: coercive provision only
sometimes exists
need conditions on preferences and income distribution
Type-3: interior (mixed-mode) equilibria:
exists if income is sufficiently polarised
richer individuals migrate to the community with voluntary provision
poorer individuals reside in the public provision community
45. Mode of provision – extension Extend the Glomm and Lagunoff (1998) analysis
a dynamic economy
congestion costs
wealth accumulation
Glomm and Lagunoff (1999)
Individuals make repeated sequential decisions
which community to inhabit?
coercive community?
voluntarist community?
The essence of the static model persists:
maybe voluntary provision exists as a within-period Nash equilibrium outcome
but if there is convergence of the wealth distribution…
…then coercive mechanism is selected in the perfect equilibrium
result may not hold if there is no wealth convergence in the long run
46. A fundamental trade-off? Consider trade-off between fundamental effects of taxation and spending policies
provision of public goods
redistributive objectives
Analyse using a two-community economy:
Tiebout mechanism interpreted as unrestricted migration between jurisdictions
Kessler and Lülfesmann (2005)
Individuals differ
in their incomes
in their tastes for a local public good
In each jurisdiction
amount of public services determined by inhabitants (majority vote)
local spending financed by linear income tax specific to the jurisdiction
47. A fundamental trade-off Individuals make a selection from this trade-off
by choice of jurisdiction through migration
by the voting mechanism
Kessler and Lülfesmann (2005) show that Tiebout-like sorting equilibria exist
if the spread in tastes is very large almost perfect sorting by preferences
otherwise, a partial sorting prevails…
…stratification into rich, poor communities is more pronounced
Existence of sorting equilibria is robust
independent of whether individuals can relocate after voting
48. Decentralisation? Is decentralisation a good idea?
at the heart of fiscal governance debate
contrast two types of model
1 Tiebout argument
positive case for decentralisation
revealed preference for public goods
2 Tax competition
negative case against decentralisation
intergovernmental competition relies on distortionary tax
inefficient outcome?
Main question
in an economy with mobile, heterogeneous consumers…
…where public goods financed by distortionary tax on mobile capital
is decentralization desirable?
? see Brueckner (2004 )
49. Decentralisation: recommendations 1 Tiebout argument for decentralisation
allow sorting by migration
(but will this lead to efficient equilibrium?)
2 Tax competition against decentralisation
if governments agree common tax rate on capital can get efficient public-good level
remove fiscal autonomy of subnational governments
a uniform tax on capital to provide a common public good
national capital tax effectively lump sum: eliminate distortion
Which dominates?
Brueckner (2004 ) uses numerical simulation
given dispersion of preferences…
gains from Tiebout sorting are likely to outweigh the loss from the capital-tax distortions
otherwise decentralization may be undesirable
50. References Banzhaf, H. S. and Walsh, R. P. (2008) “Do People Vote with Their Feet? An Empirical Test of Tiebout’s Mechanism,” American Economic Review, 98, 843-863
Bergstrom, T., L. Blume, and H. Varian (1986) “On the private provision of public goods,” Journal of Public Economics 29, 25-49.
Brueckner, J. (2004 ) “Fiscal Decentralization with Distortionary Taxation: Tiebout vs. Tax Competition,” International Tax and Public Finance, 11, 133-153}
Buchanan, J. M. (1965) “An economic theory of clubs.” Economica, 32, 1-14.
Cornes, R. and T. Sandler (1996). The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods and Club Goods (second ed.). Cambridge University Press.
Glomm, G. and R. Lagunoff (1998) “A Tiebout theory of public vs private provision of collective goods,” Journal of Public Economics, 68 , 91-112.
Glomm, G. and R. Lagunoff (1999) “A dynamic Tiebout theory of voluntary vs involuntary provision of public goods,” Review of Economic Studies, 66, 659-677.
Kessler, A. S. and C. Lülfesmann (2005) “Tiebout and redistribution in a model of residential and political choice,” Journal of Public Economics, 89, 501.528.
Pauly, M. V. (1970) “Optimality, .public. goods and local governments: A general theoretical analysis,” Journal of Political Economy, 78, 572-585.
Stiglitz, J. E. (1977) “The theory of local public goods, “in M. S. Feldstein and R. P. Inman (Eds.), The Economics of Public Services. London, UK: Macmillan.
Tiebout, C. M. (1956) “A pure theory of local expenditures,” Journal of Political Economy, 64, 416-424.