1 / 41

Contract Law: Enforcing Promises for Cooperation and Efficiency

This lecture discusses the purpose of contract law in enabling cooperation and trade, enforcing promises, and encouraging disclosure of information. It also explores the concept of reliance and its role in determining efficient breach of contract. The lecture offers examples and scenarios to help understand these concepts.

aho
Download Presentation

Contract Law: Enforcing Promises for Cooperation and Efficiency

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Econ 522Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2010 Lecture 11

  2. Logistics • Midterm will (hopefully) be returned Wednesday • HW2 also returned Wednesday • HW3 will be up later this week – due Fri Nov 5

  3. Contract law: the story so far • Contract = legally binding promise • Allow for cooperation/trade when transactions aren’t instantaneous • First purpose of contract law: enable cooperation • What promises should be enforced? • Bargain theory: those given as part of a bargain • Three elements: offer, acceptance, consideration • Efficiency: any promise both promisor and promisee wanted to be enforceable • Information • Asymmetric/private info can prevent trade; contract law can help • Second purpose: encourage efficient disclosure of information

  4. Contract law: the story so far • When should promises be broken? • Breach of contract is efficient when cost to perform > benefit of performance to promisee • Breach is in promisor’s interest when cost to perform > promisor’s liability from breach • Expectation damages: liability from breach = benefit to promisee • Leads to breach exactly when it’s efficient • We can think of this as “designing the law to internalize an externality” • Third purpose of contract law: obtain optimal commitment to performance

  5. Reliance

  6. Reliance • You expect an airplane to arrive in spring – you might… • Build yourself a hangar • Sign up for flying lessons • Buy a helmet and goggles • Reliance – investments which depend on performance • Reliance increases the value of performance to promisee • Reliance increases the social cost of breach • The fourth purpose of contract law is to secure optimal reliance

  7. When is reliance efficient? • When social benefit of reliance > social cost of reliance • Social benefit is increased benefit to promisee • (Value of airplane + hangar) – (Value of airplane without hangar) • Value is only realized if the promise is performed • Social cost is cost borne by promisee • Cost occurs whether or not promise is performed • Reliance is efficient if Increase in value of performance Probability of performance Cost ofinvestment X >

  8. Reliance and damages • Reliance is efficient if(increase in value) X (probability of performance) > (cost) • Can we design damages to get efficient reliance? • We know expectation damages lead to efficient breach • Expectation damages = expected benefit from performance • If reliance increases anticipated benefit, does it increase expectation damages in event of breach?

  9. Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000Cost of hangar = $75,000Value of plane + hangar = $600,000 Reliance and damages:example • You’re buying an airplane from me • Price is $350,000, to be paid on delivery • Airplane alone gives you benefit of $500,000 • Building a hangar costs $75,000 • Airplane with hangar gives you benefit of $600,000 • Without hangar, expectation damages = $150,000 • If you build a hangar and I fail to deliver plane, do I owe… • $150,000? (Value of original promise) • $250,000? (Value of performance after your investment) • $225,000? (Value of original promise, plus reimburse you for investment you made) • Some other amount?

  10. Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000Cost of hangar = $75,000Value of plane + hangar = $600,000 If exp damages includebenefit from reliance… • If you don’t build hangar, your payoff will be… • $150,000 if I deliver the plane ($500,000 – $350,000) • $150,000 if I breach and pay expectation damages • If you build hangar, your payoff will be… • $175,000 if I deliver the plane ($600,000 – $350,000 – $75,000) • $175,000 if I breach and pay (higher) expectation damages • So if expectation damages include the increased value of performance due to reliance investments… • You’ll invest whenever (increase in benefit) > (cost) • In this case, you’ll invest (because $100,000 > $75,000)

  11. Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000Cost of hangar = $75,000Value of plane + hangar = $600,000 If exp damages includebenefit from reliance… • If expectation damages include increased value of performance, you’ll invest for sure • Is this efficient? • Reliance is efficient if (increase in benefit) X (probability of performance) > (cost) $100,000 X (probability of performance) > $75,000 • Only efficient if probability of performance > ¾ • If probability of performance < ¾, reliance is inefficient, but happens anyway • Overreliance!

  12. Overreliance • If reliance investments increase the damages you’ll receive in the event of breach, you’ll over-rely • You’ll rely if • Efficient to rely if • So overreliance guaranteed if damages increase when you make reliance investments • Your investment causes an externality Increasein benefit Prob. of perform. Increasein damages Prob. of breach Cost ofinvestment X + X > Increasein benefit Prob. of perform. Cost ofinvestment X >

  13. Reliance and breach • Just showed: to get efficient reliance, ignore reliance investments when calculating expectation damages • But if we do that… • Then promisor’s liability from breach < promisee’s benefit from performance • Which means: inefficient breach • “Paradox of compensation” • Single “price” (damages owed) sets multiple incentives… • …impossible to set them all efficiently!

  14. So what do we do? • Cooter and Ulen: include only efficient reliance • Perfect expectation damages: restore promisee to level of well-being he would have gotten from performance if he had relied the efficient amount • So promisee rewarded for efficient reliance, not for overreliance

  15. So what do we do? • Cooter and Ulen: include only efficient reliance • Perfect expectation damages: restore promisee to level of well-being he would have gotten from performance if he had relied the efficient amount • So promisee rewarded for efficient reliance, not for overreliance • Actual courts: include only foreseeable reliance • That is, if promisor could reasonably expect promisee to rely that much

  16. Foreseeable reliance: Hadley v Baxendale • 1850s England • Hadley owned gristmill, mill shaft broke • Baxendale’s firm hired to transport shaft for repair • Baxendale shipped by boat instead of train, making it a week late • Hadley sued for the week’s lost profits • “The shipper assumed that Hadley, like most millers, kept a spare shaft. …Hadley did not inform him of the special urgency in getting the shaft repaired.” • Court listed several circumstances where broken shaft would not force mill to shut down • Ruled lost profits not foreseeable  Baxendale didn’t have to pay

  17. Another experiment:is trust a problem?

  18. A two-player game, similar to the investment/agency game • Player A starts with $10 • Chooses how much of it to give to player B • That money is tripled • Player B has $10, plus 3x whatever A gave him/her • Chooses how much (if any) to give back to player A • We’ll try the game three ways: • Anonymously – A and B don’t know who each other are • Face to face – A and B know who each other are, and can discuss the game before playing, but their actions remain private • In public – A and B play out loud in front of the whole class

  19. Default Rules

  20. Default rules • Gaps: risks or circumstances that aren’t specifically addressed in a contract • Default rules: rules applied by courts to fill gaps

  21. Default rules • Gaps: risks or circumstances that aren’t specifically addressed in a contract • Default rules: rules applied by courts to fill gaps • Writing something into a contract vs leaving a gap • Allocating a loss (ex post) • Versus allocating a risk (ex ante), before it becomes a loss

  22. What should default rules be? • Cooter and Ulen: use the rule parties would have wanted, if they had chosen to negotiate over this issue • This will be whatever rule is efficient

  23. What should default rules be? • Cooter and Ulen: use the rule parties would have wanted, if they had chosen to negotiate over this issue • This will be whatever rule is efficient • Fifth purpose of contract law is to minimize transaction costs of negotiating contracts by supplying efficient default rules • Do this by imputing the terms the parties would have chosen if they had addressed this contingency

  24. Default rules • Don’t want ambiguity in the law • So default rule can’t vary with every case • Majoritarian default rule: the terms that most parties would have agreed to • In cases where this rule is not efficient, parties can still override it in the contract • Court: figure out efficient allocation of risks, then (possibly) adjust prices to compensate

  25. Default rules • Example: probability ½, the cost of construction will increase by $2,000 • Construction company can hedge this risk for $400 • Family can’t do anything about it • Price goes up – who pays for it?

  26. Default rules • Example: probability ½, the cost of construction will increase by $2,000 • Construction company can hedge this risk for $400 • Family can’t do anything about it • Price goes up – who pays for it? • Construction company is efficient bearer of this risk • So efficient contract would allocate this risk to construction company • Should prices be adjusted to compensate?

  27. Default rules • Example: probability ½, the cost of construction will increase by $2,000 • Construction company can hedge this risk for $400 • Family can’t do anything about it • Price goes up – who pays for it? • Construction company is efficient bearer of this risk • So efficient contract would allocate this risk to construction company • Should prices be adjusted to compensate?

  28. Default rules • So, Cooter and Ulen say: set the default rule that’s efficient in the majority of cases • Most contracts can leave this gap, save on transaction costs • In cases where this rule is inefficient, parties can contract around it

  29. Default rules: a different view • Ian Ayres and Robert Gertner, “Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules” • Sometimes better to make default rule something the parties would not have wanted • To give incentive to address an issue rather than leave a gap • Or to give one party incentive to disclose information • “Penalty default”

  30. Penalty defaults: Hadley v Baxendale • Baxendale (shipper) is only one who can influence when crankshaft is delivered; so he’s efficient bearer of risk • If default rule held Baxendale liable, Hadley has no need to tell him the shipment is urgent • So Hadley might hide this information, which is inefficient • Ayres and Gertner: Ruling in Hadley was a good one, not because it was efficient, but because it was inefficient… • …but in a way that created incentive for disclosing information

  31. Penalty defaults: other examples • Real estate brokers and “earnest money” • Broker knows more about real estate law • Default rule that seller keeps earnest money encourages broker to bring it up if it’s efficient to change this

  32. Penalty defaults: other examples • Real estate brokers and “earnest money” • Broker knows more about real estate law • Default rule that seller keeps earnest money encourages broker to bring it up if it’s efficient to change this • Courts will impute missing price of a good, but not quantity • Forces parties to explicitly contract on quantity, rather than leave it for court to decide

  33. When to use penalty defaults? • Look at why the parties left a gap in contract • Because of transaction costs  use efficient rule • For strategic reasons  penalty default may be more efficient • Similar logic in a Supreme Court dissent by Justice Scalia • Congress passed a RICO law without statute of limitations • Majority decided on 4 years – what they thought legislature would have chosen • Scalia proposed no statute of limitations; “unmoved by the fear that this… might prove repugnant to the genius of our law…” • “Indeed, it might even prompt Congress to enact a limitations period that it believes appropriate, a judgment far more within its competence than ours.”

  34. Regulations(don’t expect to get to this)

  35. Default rules versus regulations • Default rules can be contracted around • Some rules cannot – immutable rules, or mandatory rules, or regulations • Fifth purpose of contract law is to minimize transaction costs of negotiating contracts by supplying efficient default rules and regulations. • Coase: if individuals are rational and there are no transaction costs, private negotiations lead to efficiency • So additional regulations can only make things worse • But when people are not rational, or when there are transaction costs/market failures, regulations may help

  36. One example of a regulation/immutable rule: derogation of public policy • Derogate, verb. detract from; curtail application of (a law) • Contracts which derogate public policy – that is, contradict a law or regulation – are not enforceable • Contracts which could only be performed by breaking a law • Contracts whose effect is to circumvent a law “if I ever work for C for less than $15/hr, I’ll work for you for $1/hr” A(other factory) B(union) C(ownership)

  37. One example of a regulation/immutable rule: derogation of public policy • Derogate, verb. detract from; curtail application of (a law) • Contracts which derogate public policy – that is, contradict a law or regulation – are not enforceable • Contracts which could only be performed by breaking a law • Contracts whose effect is to circumvent a law “if I ever work for C for less than $15/hr, I’ll work for you for $1/hr” A(other factory) B(union) C(ownership)

  38. Derogation of public policy • In general: contracts which can only be performed by breaking the law are not enforceable • But… • “A married man may be liable for inducing a woman to rely on his promise of marriage, even though the law prohibits him from marrying without first obtaining a divorce.” • “A company that fails to supply a good as promised may be liable even though selling a good with the promised design violates a government safety regulation.” • “A company that fails to supply a good as promised may be liable even though producing the good is impossible without violating an environmental regulation.” • “A promisor should be liable for breach if he knew that the promise was illegal”

  39. Expectation damages: default rule or immutable rule? • Peevyhouse v Garland Coal and Mining Co(OK Supreme Court, 1962) • Garland contracted to strip-mine coal on Peevyhouse’s farm • Contract specified Garland would restore property to original condition; Garland did not • Restoration would have cost $29,000… • …but “diminution in value” of farm only $300 • Original jury awarded $5,000 in damages, both parties appealed • Oklahoma Supreme Court reduced damages to $300

  40. Expectation damages: default rule or immutable rule? • Seems like classic case of efficient breach • Performing last part of contract would cost $29,000 • Benefit to Peevyhouses would be $300 • Efficient to breach and pay expectation damages, which is what happened • But… • Most coal mining contracts: standard per-acre diminution payment • Peevyhouses refused to sign contract unless it specifically promised the restorative work • Dissent: Peevyhouses entitled to “specific performance”

  41. We can also think about Peevyhouse in terms of penalty defaults • Which works better in this case: • Default rule allowing Garland to breach and pay diminution fee? • Default rule forcing Garland to perform restorative work? • Ayres and Gertner: default rule should “penalize” the better-informed party • Garland routinely signed contracts like these • Peevyhouses were doing this for the first time • Default rule allows Garland to pay diminution fee: they have no reason to bring it up, Peevyhouses don’t know • Default rule forces Garland to do cleanup: if that’s inefficient, they could bring it up during negotiations • In this case, specific performance would work as a penalty default

More Related