90 likes | 272 Views
The Impact of Business Environment Reforms on New Firm Registrations By Leora Klapper and Inessa Love. Discussant Comments Mary Hallward-Driemeier March 30, 2011. Contributions. Extends analysis of impact of business reforms on 3 dimensions Threshold effects on impact of reforms
E N D
The Impact of Business Environment Reforms on New Firm RegistrationsBy LeoraKlapper and Inessa Love Discussant Comments Mary Hallward-Driemeier March 30, 2011
Contributions • Extends analysis of impact of business reforms on 3 dimensions • Threshold effects on impact of reforms • Benefits of simultaneous or sequenced reforms • Whether starting-point matters • Data • Firm registration • 92 countries • Panel Can test for impact using country fixed effects, looking at impact of changes in regulations over time within a country
Outcome measured captures important slice of ‘entrepreneurship’ • Entry density (# newly registered firms/1000 working age people) • New firms that register or newly registered firms? • Bruhn 2011: few informal firms registered post-reform (Mexico) • Discussion often framed as register or not; but tied to entry decision • If not registered, would they not have entered? Or been informal? (data not available) • Limited liability companies • Demonstrate they are far more prevalent in higher income countries • Urbanization/agriculture • Affects measure of ‘density’ • Size of informal sector • But also among registered firms (see chart) • Do definitions or criterion vary across countries? • civil-common law countries • Min. capital; min labor? • Factors beyond ‘starting a business’ regulations affect choice to be LLC. Limited liability companies represent differing shares of registered firms with 5+ employees Source: Enterprise Surveys
Annual changes in entry-density are large Median annual change: 10% 75th percentile: 25%
Approach: Changes in registration process affects relative cost-benefits of registering (entry, LLC) Small reform: b < c1 < c0 Large reform: c1 <b < c0 • Costs of registration process is only a small share of total cost of being a registered firm • Are co-c1 large enough to shift the balance? • Is adjustment a change in stock of registered firms? Or change in growth of new registered firms? • Model assumes latter – does the effect persist? • What if allow multiple treatments on same DB dimension within country? • Why do countries reform? • Possible endogeneity? • Omitted variable? • Is DB capturing true costs of registration? Do changes in DB capture true changes facing firms? • Proxying for other domestic trends? • How well does DB capture what firms actually face?
Variation in dealing with regulations vary more within a country than across countries • And the ‘cost’ of high DB measures is often paid through corruption: • the frequency of bribes is higher where the de jure – de facto gap is larger. Source: Hallward-Driemeier and Pritchett, 2011. “How Business is Done and the Doing Business Indicators”
Changes in DB – aren’t necessarily reported as experienced on the ground • But in some cases where de facto has risen (or declined less), the gap between de jure and de facto has closed • Enforcement may have improved • Greater awareness of benefits of registration • Scope for corruption may have narrowed, encouraging greater entry 45o Source: Hallward-Driemeier and Pritchett, 2011. “How Business is Done and the Doing Business Indicators”
Suggestions • 1) Threshold effects • Look at role of institutional quality – does it affect the impact of a reform? • Is the threshold in the change in DB or in institutional quality (i.e. 10% change can matter, but only if the institutional quality is good enough)? • 2) Simultaneous or sequential reforms • Looked at in terms of different dimensions of ‘starting a business’ (i.e. time, cost, # procedures) • BUT • Other regulatory reforms? • Have broader DB reforms available to test • Tax reforms • Other reforms or public investments (e.g. infrastructure) that improve the business climate?
3) Whether starting-point matters? • Careful to nuance strength of findings – some evidence on minimum capital requirements; less significance for others. • And as minimal capital requirements has ‘GDP per capita’ as denominator, some of the ‘improvements’ are due to growth (which may independently encourage entry), not actual changes in the requirements. • Worth restricting to where there are actual reforms. • Reinforces likely role of institutional quality in making reforms stick • Hallward-Driemeier and Pritchett (2011) – not surprising that at upper end of DB, could make even large formal change before hits most firms’ experience or induce change in behavior. • Likely get larger impact if start at lower level – because enforcement gap is likely smaller (or institutions are stronger) • Implies previously ‘good DB’ reformers are driving the results rather than larger absolute changes in previously ‘bad reformers’ • However, for ‘good DB performers’ (low DB numbers), even large % change in DB may actually be small absolute change – harder to reconcile with model that points to comparisons of levels of costs and benefits.