310 likes | 550 Views
The emergence of neoclassical economics. ECON 434 | Spring 2011. Finishing up from last time. Alternatives to capitalism . Alternatives to capitalism . Socialism Utopian Fabian Christian Revolutionary (Marxism) Anarchism Syndicalism . Perspectives on libertarianism.
E N D
The emergence of neoclassical economics ECON 434 | Spring 2011
Finishing up from last time Alternatives to capitalism
Alternatives to capitalism • Socialism • Utopian • Fabian • Christian • Revolutionary (Marxism) • Anarchism • Syndicalism
Perspectives on libertarianism • http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2010/04/21/tea-partiers-in-tax-day-p_n_546909.html • http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=4kMxgOJK3-0&feature=fvw
Tenants of libertarianism • The modern champions of laissez-faire capitalism, libertarians prize freedom as the most important social value, and advocate replacing government with the market system wherever possible. • Forbid govt. provision of many goods (i.e. education, highways, postal service) • Abolish any laws governing • Drugs, consensual sex, pornography • Parental rights over teens • Wages and prices (including utility rates) • Military drafts
Scandinavian welfare states • In modern welfare states, resources are largely privately owned, but high taxes and a massive welfare system mean that income is distributed across the society much more equally than, for example, in the United States. • “Welfare capitalism”
Buddhist economics • The idea that "small is beautiful" stresses curbing material want as the key to dealing with scarcity, and emphasizes local self-sufficiency, and small-scale, labor-intensive technology. • Drawn from Buddhist and Hindu religious thought • Intellectual foundations from Gandhi and E.F. Schumacher (Small is Beautiful: Economics as if People Mattered)
The marginalist revolution • Application of mathematical analysis to economics begins in the mid 19th century • This new methodological approach distinguishes classical economics from neoclassical economics. • The use of formal mathematics was absent from Adam Smith’s works, for example • What is a marginal unit? What does it mean for a decision to be made “at the margin”?
The marginalist revolution cont. • Marginal decisions are an incremental process • Microeconomic analysis is based on optimization, which entails weighing marginal benefits and marginal costs. • Individuals maximize utility; firms, profits • A marginal unit is the extra (or last) unit. • In a class of 20 students, all students, technically, are the marginal student (if any student were to drop the course, 19 students would be enrolled). • Marginal changes are typically denoted with the Greek symbol delta (ΔP reads “change in price”)
Marginal analysis • (Q*, P*) optimizes individual utility (MC = MB) • To the left of Q* = Individual hasn’t consumed enough • To the right of Q* = Individual has consumed too much MC P* MB Q*
Marginal analysis cont. • The law of equal marginal advantage requires equivalent goods or similar resources to be allocated in equally advantageous ways at the margin. • Mathematically, we can write MUx/Px = MUy/Py = … • Suppose that you and your identical twin are equally strong, experienced, and intelligent. If your twin works an 8-hour day and produces $64 worth of mowed lawns while you generate $48 worth of cleaned windows with similar effort, something is wrong. You will (and should) shift into mowing lawns so that your labor resources are allocated equally advantageously, at $8 per hour instead of the $6 per hour you have been earning.
Marginal analysis cont. • Would you eat less from a menu where prices are a la carte or where fixed price is charged for a buffet? • You probably eat less from a menu where prices are a la carte than if a restaurant charges a fixed price for a buffet; “all-you-can-eat” pricing causes you to view the cost of extra food as zero.
Marginal analysis cont. • Other examples of marginal analysis in economics: • People's time must be divided between work and leisure so that the gain in income from the last hour an individual works (the individual's wage) just equals the subjective value of the last hour of leisure enjoyed. • The last dollar a firm pays for labor must generate the same amount of extra production (and profit) as the last dollar spent on capital or land. • The dollar value to a consumer of the right to consume a particular good must equal the value of other production that society sacrifices in making that marginal unit of the good available to that consumer.
Calculus and marginal analysis • Isaac Newton and Gottfried Wilhelm von Leibniz independently discover calculus around 1675. • Takes over 170 years before calculus is applied to economics.
Examples of calculus and marginal analysis (per Cournot) • Firms want to maximize profits. • Profit = Total revenue – total cost • Profit = P•Q – wL – rK • Profit = pF(K, L) – wL – rK • To maximize: Take the derivate and set equal to 0. • 0 = p dF(K, L)/dK – r • p dF(K, L)/dk = r • r/p = dF(K, L)/dk • The firm hires capital until the price of capital (r/p) equals the marginal product.
Early foundations of marginalism • W. S. Jevons (1835-1882) • “Bygones are forever bygones” • Sunk costs are irrelevant for future decisions. • Example: Waiting in line • Diamond-water paradox and marginal pricing
W.S. Jevons cont. • Theory of Political Economy (1871) • Diminishing marginal utility • Equimarginal principle • Sunspot theory and the beginnings of econometrics • Prices are determined by supply and demand • Contrast with classical assumption that demand is always adequate • Say’s law: Supply creates its own demand
Forerunners of marginal analysis • Jules Dupuit • Price discrimination: Occurs when virtually identical units of a good are sold at different prices, and price differentials do not reflect different production costs. • Popular examples include movie tickets (i.e., different prices for teens, senior citizens) and coupons • Requirements for price discrimination • The firm must have some amount of market power • The firm must know the demand schedule (the consumers’ willingness to pay) • The firm must be able to prevent resale (arbitrage)
Types of price discrimination • 1st degree price discrimination • Charge each consumer their willingness to pay. • This eliminates all consumer surplus; it also eliminates all deadweight loss. • Creates conditions of perfect competition • Because price discrimination can eliminate the deadweight loss associated with monopolies, it can make monopolistic behavior efficient
The effects of 1st degree price discrimination Consumer surplus 1st degree price discrimination eliminates all consumer surplus and all deadweight loss. The elimination of deadweight loss makes the monopoly efficient (as if in a state of perfect competition). Deadweight loss MC P* Profit Q* Producer surplus D MR
A monopoly with 1st degree price discrimination • Price discrimination on a person-by-person basis where each is charged the most they are willing to pay (the firm knows each person’s demand curve) • Marginal revenue = demand • No consumer surplus; all producer surplus MC D
Price discrimination cont. • 2nd degree price discrimination: Charge different per unit prices for different amounts of a good for strategic reasons • Bulk discounts • Block pricing: first bunch of goods you buy is expensive; the next bunch is less expensive • 3rd degree price discrimination: Charge each group of consumers a different price based on their willingness to pay • Classify individuals into groups and charge all they will bear
Forerunners of marginal analysis • A.A. Cournot • First to clearly define a demand curve mathematically • Profit maximizing rule: MR = MC • Employs calculus for optimization problems (see the “Examples of Calculus in Marginal Analysis” slide) • Distinguishes changes in demand from changes in quantity demanded
A.A. Cournot • Distinguishes changes in demand from changes in quantity demanded S1 S0 S0 P P D1 D0 D0 Q Q Change in demand Change in quantity demanded
Cournot duopoly model • Sets the foundation for modern game theory • Two firms strategically choose their output (quantity-adjusting model) • P = a – bq • Marginal cost = c(q) • Profit firm x(q1, q2) = p*qx – c(qx) • Profit firm 1(q1, q2) = q1[a – b(q1 + q2)] – c(q1) • Profit firm 2(q1, q2) = q2[a – b(q1 + q2)] – c(q2)
Cournot duopoly model • Profit firm 1(q1, q2) = q1[a – b(q1 + q2)] – c(q1) • Re-write the equation: q1[a – bq1 – bq2] – c(q1) • Re-write the equation: q1a – bq12 – bq1q2 – c(q1) • 0 = aq1 – bq12 – bq1q2 – c(q1) • 0 = a – 2bq1 – bq2 – c • 2bq1 = a – bq2 – c • Q1 = (a – bq2 – c)/(2b) • This is firm one’s best response function.
Cournot duopoly model • The point: The quantity at which a firm decides to produce is dependent upon the quantity (and subsequent quantity adjustments) of another firm • Assumes continuous strategic interaction between firms • Compare to Bertrand, who said that firms would adjust prices • This anticipates a larger debate between Keynesians and traditional macroeconomists