1 / 20

R&D Investment and Output Competition by Supply-Managed Producer Associations

R&D Investment and Output Competition by Supply-Managed Producer Associations. Zoe Campbell James Vercammen University of British Columbia CAES/AAEA Annual Meetings Portland (July 30, 2007). Producer-Funded R&D.

andrew
Download Presentation

R&D Investment and Output Competition by Supply-Managed Producer Associations

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. R&D Investment and Output Competition by Supply-Managed Producer Associations Zoe Campbell James Vercammen University of British Columbia CAES/AAEA Annual Meetings Portland (July 30, 2007)

  2. Producer-Funded R&D • Public sector agricultural R&D is gradually being replaced by private sector R&D in many countries (Alston, Pardey, and Roseboom 1998) • As well, farmers are increasingly active in R&D through producer association check-off schemes (Alston, Pardey, and Smith 1998) • Return to agricultural R&D is generally high, both for producers and for society, so R&D investment is typically inefficiently low (Alston, Marra, Pardey and Watt 1998, Brinkman 2004)

  3. Producer Associations in Supply-Managed Industries • Canada utilizes supply management for the production of dairy, poultry, eggs and other select commodities • Producers in supply-managed industries are required to contribute a portion of their sales to their association (i.e., a mandatory levy) • A sizeable fraction of the total levy is ear-tagged for R&D • Dairy Farmers of Canada invests annually up to $1.7 million in health and nutrition research, and dairy production research

  4. R&D Incentives with & without SM • SM schemes are often criticized because of non-competitive domestic pricing, restricted imports and a constrained operating environment for processors • Can SM schemes also be criticized on the basis of inefficient R&D incentives? • Specifically, do producers in SM industries contribute less to R&D because of restricted domestic production and import controls? • Would Canadian producers participate more actively in R&D if a future WTO agreement eliminates SM and allows for free-trade and competition?

  5. Theoretical Context • Theoretical analysis of R&D incentives generally assume a small set of imperfectly competitive firms and R&D spillovers • Agricultural firms are perfectly competitive, but the association making the R&D decisions has monopoly power and faces no spillovers • There are no models which compare R&D incentives when both R&D and production are monopolized (current SM) with R&D incentives when R&D is monopolized and production is competitive (dismantled SM)

  6. Paper Objectives • Theoretically compare R&D investment incentives with SM versus a competitive closed economy (R&D decisions are still monopolized) • Expand comparison by allowing for an open border with the U.S. (now producer association competes for market share) • Initially assume identical demand and production costs prior to R&D selection to isolate pure competition effects • Then assume Canada is a net importer prior to R&D to account for “size of the market” effects of SM reform • Assume R&D reduces cost rather than creates new products

  7. Review of Theoretical Issues • Schumpeter (1942) argues that monopoly and large scale promote R&D investment because more benefits can be captured and the economic environment is more stable • Others argue that competition promotes R&D investment because firms that fail to innovate operate at higher relative cost and lose market share • In an oligopoly environment, spillovers reduce a firm’s R&D incentives because of impact on rival firm’s cost (d’Aspermont and Jacquemin 1988) • Firms have an incentive to set up research joint ventures and/or R&D cartels, and these are typically socially efficient (Kamien, Muller and Zang 1992)

  8. Closed Economy Result 1: In a closed economy, R&D incentives are stronger with versus without SM • In a competitive environment with relatively elastic demand, consumers capture large share of R&D surplus • SM retains higher fraction of R&D surplus for producers • Suppose supply is linear with slope  and intercept c, and suppose demand function is P(Q) • Assume R&D decreases c • SM: Competition:

  9. Closed Economy Illustrated R&D Induced Shift SM Competitive Gain is positive Gain is small or negative

  10. Open Economy • In the closed economy model, the SM producer association faces no competition • Competition in the form of free trade should induce the producer association to invest more in R&D

  11. Open Economy Model • Demand: P = H – Q for home P = F – Q for foreign • Supply: MC = h + Q for home MC = f + Q for foreign Where: h = h0 – xh - xF f = f0 – xF - xH  (0, 1) is the spillover parameter • Cost of R&D is quadratric • Let xSM, xC and xT denote optimal R&D levels for H with SM, closed competition and open competition

  12. Pure Competition Effects: No SpilloverTwo Countries are identical prior to R&D Decision Country H Country F Excess Supply Excess Demand Becomes net importer due to lower R&D Becomes net exporter due to higher R&D

  13. Result 2: Pure Competition Effect • Suppose trading countries are identical prior to R&D, and suppose spillovers are zero. In two-stage game equilibrium: xC < xSM < xT • The concern over market share lost to imports induces the producer association to invest relatively more aggressively

  14. Result 3: Impact of Spillover • Suppose trading countries are identical prior to R&D • An increase in the spillover parameter, , reduces optimal R&D • For a low to moderate value of  xC < xT < xSM • For a relatively high value of  xT < xC < xSM

  15. Intuition for Result 3 • As H increases x, F also becomes more competitive due to the spillover • H will therefore choose a smaller value of x to account for this externality • There exists a critical value for  which ensures R&D expenditures are equal with SM and with open borders • If R&D spillover is high (i.e., above critical value), then dismantling SM will result in a lower level of producer contributions to R&D

  16. R&D Joint Ventures • R&D joint ventures (RJV) are common in industries such as biotechnology and telecommunications • In our model, RJV implies agreeing to share R&D results ( = 1) while still choosing x non-cooperatively • Kamien, Muller and Zang (1992) show that with imperfect competition, RJV result in lower R&D levels but higher profits for each firm • Similar results are obtained in this competitive model of R&D: raising  increases surplus for producers and society, but reduces R&D spending • Considerable evidence of R&D cooperation in agriculture

  17. Net Importer Scenario • The assumption of equal-sized trading partners is now relaxed • Assume that with open borders, H is a net importer prior to choosing R&D • Opening the border therefore reduces the size of H’s market (refer to this as the “market scale” effect) • Walk through the two alternative scenarios of: (a) no spillovers; (b) positive spillovers

  18. Result 4: Market Scale Effects • Suppose H is a net importer after SM is dismantled but prior to R&D choice. Suppose the spillover is zero. • If pre-R&D imports are small, then the competition effect dominates and xT > xSM • If pre-R&D imports are relatively large, then the market scale effect dominates and xT < xSM • One of these two scenarios corresponds to the Canadian case

  19. Result 5: Market Scale and Spillovers • Suppose H is a net importer after SM is dismantled but prior to R&D choice. Suppose the spillover is positive. • An increase in the spillover induces F to invest less heavily in R&D • An increase in the spillover initially induces H to invest more heavily in R&D but eventually induces H to invest less heavily in R&D • In other words, for small values of β, R&D choices for H and F are strategic substitutes and for larger values of β, the choices are strategic complements

  20. Conclusions • Despite a large literature on R&D incentives, no obvious implications for SM • Considerable theoretical ambiguity regarding whether R&D incentives will improve or worsen with a dismantling of SM • Framework is highly simplistic • Additional theoretical and empirical work warranted Financial support from Canadian Agricultural Innovation Research Network (CAIRN gratefully acknowldged

More Related