90 likes | 266 Views
IPR and Innovation. Ashish Arora Heinz School, Carnegie Mellon University. IPR and Innovation. Socially efficient level of R&D (conditional on existing firms) Efficient allocation of R&D input Commercialization Cumulative innovation and dynamics Institutions of knowledge generation.
E N D
IPR and Innovation Ashish Arora Heinz School, Carnegie Mellon University
IPR and Innovation • Socially efficient level of R&D (conditional on existing firms) • Efficient allocation of R&D input • Commercialization • Cumulative innovation and dynamics • Institutions of knowledge generation
Socially efficient level of R&D • Incentives to innovate – what is the role of patents • Patents less important than other first mover advantage and commercialization capabilities (e.g., Yale, CMU surveys) • Median patent of low value – patent renewal studies (e.g., Pakes, Schankerman) – 25% ESR • But average value of patents may be significantly higher (e.g., Gambardella et al.)
Patents not used for a majority of innovations in the vast majority of industries Patent protection is valuable in all industries, even in industries that do not patent much. Patent Premium, selected industries Source: Arora, Ceccagnoli and Cohen, “R&D and the Patent Premium”, NBER, 2004
Efficient allocation of R&D effort • Entry – mixed evidence • Interaction between IPR and market power – retard entry (e.g., MSFT) • French org. chemical industry destroyed by excessively broad patents. • Patents used to coordinate cartels in chemicals in pre WWII • Patents by non producers promotes entry in chemicals (Lieberman) • Patents promote vertical specialization • Pharma firms increasingly focusing on marketing rather than R&D • Patents (and IPR broadly) may also be used to prevent vertical entry (e.g., software)
Find positive effect: Gans, Hsu, and Stern (RJE,2002): presence of patent increases the likelihood that startup licenses to an incumbent rather than enter commercializing Yang and Maskus (W.P., 2000): positive relationship between IPRs regimes and licensing by U.S. MNCs. Nagaoka (WP, 2002): using data for Japanese firms, find weak patent regimes associated with an greater fraction of transfers to an affiliate rather than unaffiliated firm Smith (JIE, 2001): US firms more likely to export or directly manufacture rather than license technology in countries with weak patent regimes. No Effect? Other studies cast doubts on the link between patent strength and the extent or form of international technology licensing Fink (WP, 1997), using German data Fosfuri (WP, 2003) in the chemical sector Cassiman and Veugelers (2002) do not find that the patent strength encourages Belgian firms to enter into collaborative R&D arrangements. Branstetter, Fisman, and Foley (NBER WP, 2002), using US data, find no evidence of an increase of technology licensing to unaffiliated parties for countries that strengthened patent protection. (But they see an increase in transfer to affiliate.) Commercialization –Patent Protection and Licensing: Mixed Evidence • Impact of patents on licensing conditioned by presence of complementary capabilities
10% Change in Patent Effectiveness Leads to: Source: Arora & Ceccagnoli “Patenting and Licensing”, Management Science, forthcoming
Dynamics • Cumulative innovation (e.g., Scotchmer, Green and Scotchmer, Merges and Nelson) • Biotech produces anecdotal evidence of problems • BRCA & Myriad • Stem Cells and Geron • Murray & Stern; Sampat • Anticommons (Heller and Eisenberg) • Empirical basis weak (e.g., Walsh et al, 2004 for commercial research and Walsh et al. 2005 for large sample academic research) • Problem may arise in future with full genome screening and gene chips
Institutions: Biggest problem area • Major threat to non market based institutions (e.g., David; Gambardella and Hall) • Many (all?) of biomed problem patent in US are university / non profit based patents • BRCA – Univ of Utah • Stem Cells – Wisconsin • Canavan – Miami • Oncomouse – Harvard