390 likes | 550 Views
Consumers and behavioral IO Prof Colin Camerer. What happens in industrial structure and consumer choice if agents are limited in rationality or willpower? Ellison (07): A. Firms are limitedly rational B. Consumers are limitedly rational, firms respond
E N D
Consumers and behavioral IOProf Colin Camerer • What happens in industrial structure and consumer choice if agents are limited in rationality or willpower? • Ellison (07): • A. Firms are limitedly rational • B. Consumers are limitedly rational, firms respond • C. Scope for regulation? (e.g. consumer protection) • Evidence from household finance, etc.
Behavioral IOProf Colin Camerer • Firms are limitedly rational • Cyert and March 56 • Business entry (Camerer-Lovallo 99) • Corporate finance (e.g. overconfident CEO’s Malmendier, mergers) • ε-equilibrium in Cournot, Bertrand competition • Fairness and learning in price matching experiments
Firms: Limits on firm rationality • Behavioral theories of the firm (50s) • Largely died out. Why? • Did not have agency theory etc. to work with • Why wouldn’t bad managers be replaced? • Poor sparse data • What is an “organizational routine”? • Due for revisit? • “routines” of organizations are cognitive, correlating devices (Kreps 90) • Does appear that firms get stuck repeating success of the past, have trouble changing (e.g. GM, Sears) • Poor governance can explain non-profit-max’n • Better data
Limits on firm rationality • Managerial overconfidence • High rate of business failure. Why? • Business entry experiments (Cam-Lovallo 99) • Top c+5 entrants share $50. Others get -$10 • Ranked by random numbers or skill (trivia)
Exps 1-4 typical recruiting, exps 5-8 self selection for skill
ε-equilibrium and pricing: Small ε can have large IO effects • ε-equilibrium, approximate best responses • Bertrand duopoly: Set prices, consumer buys cheapest • both sellers price at marginal cost • But there are mixedε-equilibrium (Baye-Morgan 04 RAND) • Can earn (2επm)1/2-ε from deviating (p>cost) • e.g. if ε=.01πm industry profit is .26πm • mild deviations produce strong pressure away from perfect competition • Cournot quantity competition, D(p)=1-p • Quantities in range (1/3)±(2/3)(ε)1/2 are ε-equil. (q=1/3 is comp.) • Includes monopoly (q=1/4 each) for ε>1/64
Bertrand price matching with loyalty rewards (Capra, Goeree, Gomez, Holt AER ‘99) • Players 1, 2 pick integer prices [80,200] ¢ Price is P=min(P1,,P2) Low price firm earns P+R (R>1) High price firm earns P-R • What happens?
Example: Price matching with loyalty rewards (Capra, Goeree, Gomez, Holt AER ‘99) • Players 1, 2 pick prices [80,200] ¢ Price is P=min(P1,,P2) Low price firm earns P+R High price firm earns P-R • What happens? • Rational theory: competition prices go to 80 • Always want to undercut by 1 unit
Intuition: Suppose p uniform Move from p to p+1 1/121 lose R were tied, now high 1/121 lose R+1 Were low, now tied (200-(P+1))/121 gain 1 by raising price Pays iff p<200-2R-2 Pressure away from Nash QRE for various R
Cognitive hierarchy model(Camerer, Ho, Chong QJE 04) • 0-step thinkers randomize • K-step thinkers respond to 0…k-1 play • Distribution f(k) is Poisson(τ) • Pricing: Step k chooses 200-2R-(k-1) • Prices approximately 187-1.56R (τ=1.5)
Price matching data over time CH predictions • R=5 179 • R=10 171 • R=20 156 • R=25 148 • R=50 109 • R=80 62
Influence of low (79) and high advice (119) with R=5 (Cabrera-Capra-Gomez 04) • No advice (median 100) • Low advice (79) • Median 81 • High advice (119) • Median 114
B. Consumers are limitedly rational, firms anticipate or respond 1. Rules of thumb in following other consumers 2. Search costs/impatience (old sales models reinterpreted) (no work on this) 3. Procrastination (gyms, Wertenbroch) 4. Hidden fees 5. Reference-dependence & sticky pricing 6. Learning 7. Regulation
1. Rules of thumb • Smallwood-Conlisk QJE 79 • rational confirmity is “a massive game theory problem with all other consumers”, too difficult • rule is a shortcut for consumers…and theorists (don’t have to endogenize it) • K brands, breakdown probability bk (quality measure), switches to h with probability mh(t)s • s=0 random • s=1 “ask one friend” • s ∞ always pick most popular (brand obsession) • Results: • s<1 better products become more popular, but all survive • s=1 better product dominates in the long run • s>1 bad product can dominate if initial m(0) is high • Typical of results: Sensitive to nature of word of mouth
3. Pricing procrastinators • Blockbuster…huge profit from late fees, forecasting error + loss-aversion? • Credit card “teaser rates” (Ausubel AER 91, Shui + Aus.) • Only 70% pay off balance, average household balance $5,000 • Netflix– pay a monthly fee for movies…but don’t get around to watching them! • Per movie fee may be large (data?) • Price discrimination through impatience • Discriminate by demand based on impatience • Movie openings (Star Wars) (now DVD sales > box office gross) • hardcover books • Rebates • Consumers plan to cash in rebates, only 50% do so (FTC) • 10% of rebate checks never cashed!
Pricing virtuous goods: Gyms I • Health clubs (Della Vigna & Malmendier, 04 QJE 05 AER) • Nonlinear two-part monopoly pricing: Membership F, per-use fee p, user cost c distributed cdf G(c) Firm (F,p)….consumer acc pay F, choose Ex pay c,p…… earn b , choose N pay 0 …….. earn 0 rej earn time 0………............time 1…............……………………………..time 2 • Consumers hyperbolic with parameters Naïve hyp =1 :Plans to choose E, earns cutoff But when t=1, E is cutoff is
Gyms II • Cutoffs on cost that generate gym attendance + G(c) probability of going • E.g. p(going) is • forecasting error is • Firm’s optimization problem: Max profits while forecasting participation
Gyms III • Pricing exponential discounters (β=1) • p*=a (price=marginal cost), F* makes participation constraint bind • Pricing hyperbolic discounters (β<1) • p*<a and F* above exponential case • Two types love this contract for different reasons: • Sophisticates like low p* to induce them to go • They prefer a high F, low p* contract to buy self-control • (May prefer high F to create “sunk cost fallacy”, not in model) • Naifs like low p* because they think they will go a lot • Naifs cross-subsidize sophisticates. How to skim naifs? • Moneyback guarantee with high unrefundable payment? • Evidence: F around $300/yr, per-visit fee=$15 • Average visits cost $19/visit. Indicates some naifs
4. Why hasn’t internet created price wars? Obfuscation & hidden fees (G+S Ellison2 04) • Similar to product differentiation
Hidden “shrouded” add-ons (Gabaix-Laibson QJE 06) • Bank fees, mutual fund mgt fees, hotels, printers • Base good (p) + add-ons (a) + substitutes (e) (e.g. bring water to hotel). Price a<b, e<b. • Firms hide/show…. Consumers buy……….observe a, buy add-on prices p,a…….........……………………………………………………… time 0 time 1 time 2 • Sophisticates (α%) update about hidden a, can substitute e • Myopes (1- α%) when visible λ% anticipate price a, 1- λ% do not notice
Hidden add-ons II • D(x) is probability of buying for relative surplus x • Define α† =1-e/b and μ=D(0)/D’(0) • μ=0 corresponds to perfect competition (D’(0) sensitivity to x) • μ--> ∞ insensitivity ( high profit) • Prop 1: • Case 1: α<α† not many sophisticates • firms hide add-on price a • p*= μ-(1- α)b, a*=b charge highest add-on price, subsidize base good • Sophisticates know, buy substitute e. Welfare loss because e is costly • Case 2: α>α†many sophisticates • p*= μ-e, b=e sophisticates police the market, everyone substitutes
Hidden add-ons: Why doesn’t competition work? • Making customers sophisticated isn’t always profitable • (Case 1) sophisticates like hidden add-ons! They get a base-good subsidy and save p*-e. Naïve don’t perceive add ons (or optimistically don’t think they will need them)
5. Loss-aversion & pricing(Heidhues & Koszegi, 04) • Personal equilibrium(Rabin & Koszegi 04): • Consumers create reference point (matches expected purchase) • Loss-averse (λ) toward loss of money or goods (value v) • Timing Firms pick F(p)……..consumer forms beliefs…. price p, cost c realized….shock realized…consumer buys • Shock h(w) to consumer value unique-fies demand (Prop 2)
Loss-aversion results • Price stickiness (Prop 3) • For substantial loss-aversion, firms choose discrete prices • Prices don’t vary smoothly with cost c (surprising) • “menu costs” empirics, Kayshap et al QJE 02? • Intuition: At a price p, consumers dislike foregoing a lower price, dislike paying more; incentivizes firms to lump prices together • Cf. “kinked” demand curve (1930’s econ) to explain sticky prices…but in this model it is derived endogeneously • Countercyclical markups (shrink in booms, grow in busts) • Explains puzzle of fixed consumer prices and wages shortages in recession, excess supply in booms
6. Learning • Perhaps consumers can learn • Time scale of learning, and forgetting, are crucial • Agarwal, Driscoll, Laibson, Gabaix (07) • 128,000 credit card customers, 3 yrs, 100M transactions • Three kinds of fee “mistakes” • Late ($30-35 + can trigger APR increase) • Over limit ($30-35 +) • Cash advance (max($5, 3%X, APR 16%)
Learning and forgetting (reinforcement) • Stock of past fees Ft-1 • Learning (β) is 20%/mo • extra late fee reduces p(late) 20% • Forgetting (δ) is 15%/mo • 1/γ is “saturation” (limit of F/(1+ γF)), around 15
Phone calling plans • Miravete AER 03 • Data from 1986 Texas • Flat fee ($18.70/mo) vs linear rate • Generally underestimate usage • 90% do not switch across three months • 60% on linear plan see they could pay less on flat fee, switch (save $5) • Rational switching occurs because few make mistakes, and mistakes are transparent • Grubb 06 • College cell phone plans • Narrow confidence intervals–- are sometimes surprised at how much they talk • Result: Overconfidence choose the wrong contract and pay high overage
7. Regulation • What about consumer protection? • Private solutions • Learning • May be slow • Some decisions are early and irreversible or rare (durables, houses, education, wedding & children, funeral homes…) • Advice • Informal (need to understand “wisdom of crowds”) • Professional (agency problem: High fees, kickbacks, etc.) • Reputation • Competition • Depends on bundling education & products (e.g. Palm Pilot) • Depends on fighting status quo bias and value of negative ads • Class action lawsuits (for many small-harm cases) • Media reporting
My (our) view • I am not an advocate for frequent changes in laws and constitutions. But laws and constitutions must go hand in hand with progress of the human mind. -- Thomas Jefferson
Public solutions: • Taxation • “Sin” taxes to reduce internalities from temptation • Alcohol, cigarettes, gambling,… fatty food? • Restricting contract terms • Cooling off • Must opt in to auto-renew (negative option) • Judicious use of the “best” default option • Consumer education • Teach high school economics!
Central empirical questions • Heterogeneity • Interaction of naïve & sophisticated (Camerer-Fehr Sci 06l) • Do sophisticated protect naïve or do firms sort them? • Endogeneity of thinking • Will consumers gather more information when they think they might make mistakes? • Not if low knowledge is correlated with low self-knowledge (e.g. Dunning et al psychology) • Disclosure • How to disclose simply without confusing consumers further? • Moral hazard • Will public regulation crowd out private consumer sophistication? • E.g.? Adjustment post-communist regimes (North Koreans, East Germans after reunification)
Crowding out of consumer vigilance • “In a regulated industry, however, there’s a tendency for consumers to let up on their vigilance. They mistakenly believe that the government is looking out for them, and that’s simply not possible all the time…Rogue [web] sites can’t be stopped through regulation. They can only be stopped through the adherence of caveat emptor” – Calvin Ayre, CEO Bodog (Costa Rican online gambling site)
FTC concerns • Sect. 5 of the FTC Act • “…unfair or deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce are declared unlawful” • Deception • Fraud/false claims • Misleading claims (overstatement, implied…) • Usually clear (e.g. magnet bracelet to lose weight, permanent hair dye) • “Unfair” • “representation, omission or practice that is likely to mislead the consumer acting reasonably in the circumstances, to the consumer’s detriment” • Scientific/regulatory challenge: What is “acting reasonably”? System 1 or does it require system 2?
Conclusion: Behavioral IO • Recipe: • A. Pick a consumer pattern– optimism, loss-aversion, inertia, limited attention... • E.g. optimism about phone minutes fixed minutes calling plans • Analyze: Does competition erase it? • B. Pick a market pattern (e.g. $9.99 pricing, high cosmetics markups) • Explain. Can it be derived as optimal?
Where do behavioral IO assumptions come from? • Reduced-form assumptions (Ellison) • Rule of thumb about social learning • Computational complexity of states • Fershtman-Kalai 93, Rubinstein 86+ • * Psychological empirical regularities • Quasi-hyp’ic and gyms, business entry, consumer search… • Opinion: Empirical basis * is better. Why? • Have to pass an empirical test eventually • Models with correct assumptions more likely to make correct market predictions • Empirics guides which of many modelling directions to go
Open questions • Can firms always create new hidden add-ons? • Markets for rare purchases (houses) • Viral marketing/word of mouth • How well do experts/advice/supershoppers. • Positive legal role for standardization to fight obfuscation? • Legal: How to regulate? Forcing disclosure has two effects • i. Informs consumers • ii. Penalizes firms who profit by exploitation • Simple disclosure is challenging though