1 / 44

Moving Viewpoint: what makes human subjects different from computer agents?

Moving Viewpoint: what makes human subjects different from computer agents?. Sobei H. Oda Kyoto Sangyo University. The Sixth International Workshop on Agent-based Approaches in Economic and Social Complex Systems National Chengchi University, Taipei 14 November 2009. Computer Agents.

ashton-wong
Download Presentation

Moving Viewpoint: what makes human subjects different from computer agents?

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Moving Viewpoint:what makes human subjects differentfrom computer agents? Sobei H. Oda Kyoto Sangyo University The Sixth International Workshop on Agent-based Approaches in Economic and Social Complex Systems National Chengchi University, Taipei 14 November 2009

  2. Computer Agents Program Action Dynamics Human Subjects Dynamics Strategy Action known observable unknown

  3. reversed × 4 × 4 Allais’ Paradox TWD400 (20 per cent) > TWD300 (25 per cent) TWD400 (80 per cent) < TWD300 (100 per cent) 100% is special, while difference between 99% and 98% is a matter of degree.

  4. Hyperbolic Discounting 22 Feb. 2010 23 Feb. 2010 TWD100000 < TWD100100 1 day 96 70 80 97 98 99 60 50 6 1 day 30 3 40 2 5 4 7 8 9 10 20 0 day 100 21 31 81 11 2 10 97 9 61 8 51 7 41 6 99 5 71 4 98 3 (in 100 days) < (in 101 days) - 99 - 98 - 60 - 97 - 96 - 1 - 2 - 3 - 4 - 5 - 30 - 7 - 8 - 9 - 20 - 6 - 40 - 50 - 70 - 80 - 10 - 100 days 0 day reversed - 96 - 99 - 80 - 8 - 6 - 5 - 4 - 98 - 7 - 2 - 3 - 70 - 60 - 50 - 40 - 30 - 20 - 10 - 9 - 97 - 1 - 100 days 0 day TWD100000 (today) > TWD100100 (tomorrow) Nov. 2009 Feb. 2010 14 15 16 17 ・ ・ ・ ・ ・ 21 22

  5. TWD100000 (in 100 d.) < TWD100100 (in 101 d.) but TWD100000 (today) > TWD100100 (tomorrow) cannot be rational (maintained) TWD4000 (20 %) > TWD3000 (25 %) but TWD4000 (80 %) < TWD3000 (100 %) can be rational Similarity and Difference between Allais’ Paradox and Hyperbolic Discounting

  6. Kyoto Experimental Economics Laboratory (KEEL) fMRI at Brain Activity Imaging Centre

  7. Combination of alternatives

  8. choice presentation choice presentation A today 4000 yen 80 % B 2 weeks 5000 yen 100 % B today 8000 yen 40 % A today 4000 yen 100 % 1-5 seconds 1-5 seconds 12 seconds + + + decision making decision making time

  9. Results (Green-Blue) • BA39 is involved in calculation (?) BA39 OFC

  10. Results (Blue-Green) Self-projection parahippocampal gyrus precuneus neural activity in these regions tracks the revealed subjective value of delayed rewards. Kable & Glimcher (Nature Neuroscience 2007) striatum PCC PFC

  11. OFC parahippocampal gyrus • Self Projection reflects the workings of the same core brain network. Remember past to imagine future. Why have we memory? Because with memory we can make better decisions and have greater chance to survive.

  12. Self-Projection (Bucker and Carroll, TRENDS in Cognitive Science 2006) Remembering Prospection Theory of Mind Navigation

  13. Self Projection as Moving viewpoint Narrator navigation Past Self Future Self Present Self remembering prospection Another Person theory of mind

  14. Self-projection PFC precuneus parahippocampal gyrus • The regions contain precuneus and parahippocampal gyrus, which are considered to be activated when people are involved in complicated decision-making. • Together with other observations, it seems to support self-projection, suggesting also why people reveal such intertemporal preference that does not allow a simple explanation.

  15. annual discounting factors No convergence is observed. Why? テキスト Frederick, Loewenstein and O'Donghue (JEL2002)

  16. Questions; (Environmant) Intertemporal choice Risky choice Brain fMRI Self-projection Calculation (?) more complicated Observation lab field Answers; (Behaviors) Instable Stable

  17. stimulus condition insider fMRI conscious thinking outsider unconscious process behaviour

  18. At least one of you have a white hat on your head. Can you tell whether your hat is white or not? Yasugi and Oda (2002, 2003)

  19. She (A) knows that my hat or her hat or both hats are white; she does not know whether her hat is white or not; she knows whether my hat is white or not. My hat is white. Girl B’s inference I (B) know: inference I (B) know:

  20. She (B) has a white hat on her head; at least one of us wears a white hat. where My hat is white or not. Girl A’s inference I (A) know: inference I (A) does not know:

  21. She (B) has a white hat on her head; at least one of us wears a white hat. My hat is white My hat is not white I (A) know: I (A) know: I (A) know: I (A) do not know whether my hat is white or not. (Yasugi and Oda 2002, 2003)

  22. Preference: what they prefer Information: what they know Options: what they can do Human behaviour Jumping out of the system (Hofstader 1979) Action: what they do inference emotion, instinct, experience, etc.: what they feel consciously or unconsciously

  23. Jumping out controllable Jumping out uncontrollable

  24. Nash Equilibrium Player A’s Reaction Curve Player B’s Reaction Curve Bertrand Duopoly with product differentiation • Participants:Class:140 • LAB:58 • All pairs are reshuffled randomly • All players’ decisions are posted simultaneously

  25. Participants/experiments: Max 28 Perticipants/experiments:120-142

  26. Percentage of students who chosePrice=3: Nash Equilibrium strategy %

  27. Percentage of students who chosePrice = 7: Pareto optimal strategy %

  28. Percentage of students who chosePrice = 2: What strategy? %

  29. Choosing 2 is the unique Dominant strategy foreach player if they maximises not their profit but the difference between their profits and their opponents’. Player A’s profit >Player B’s profit Player A’s profit <Player B’s profit Player A’s profit =Player B’s profit

  30. Without Monetary rewards students played not P=3 to maximize their profits but P=2 to beat their opponents, which are also confirmed in the debriefing questionnaires.

  31. (8,8) 1st mover profit =2624 2nd mover profit =2624 1st mover’s Reaction Cuarve Maximum 1st mover’s profit on the 2nd mover’s reaction Curve: SPNE 2nd mover’s Reaction Curve: 2nd mover’s SPNE strategy 1st mover’s SPNE strategy Cournot-Stackelberg Duopoly • All pairs are fixed. • First 1st movers’ decisions are shown and then 2nd movers make decisions

  32. Percentage of pairs who realised Nash Equilibrium: (13,5) • Without Money are students more “rational”?

  33. 2nd player’s strategy (3, 10) 1st mover Profit 1362 2nd mover Profit 4540 Nash Equilibrium most advantageous for the 2nd mover 1st player’s strategy 1st mover’s profit increases 2nd mover’s profit increases (13,5) 1st mover Profit 3172 2nd mover Profit 1220 Nash Equilibria

  34. 2nd mover’s choice2nd movers are more Submissive in Classroom. Laboratory Classroom Experiment 3 Profit table Practically Ultimatum game Cooperation seeking (?) No-conditional accept Conditional accept Reject Pareto optimal 2nd mover’s Reaction Curve

  35. Dynamics of 1st mover’s choice Classroom Period 1 Lab Period 1 3 8 13 3 6 8 13 Classroom Period 10 Lab Period 11 3 6 8 13 3 8 13

  36. In the classroom the second movers were ready for accepting the SPNE, which is the Nash Equilibrium least favorable to them. In the debriefing Questionnaires they were only too happy to give a rational explanation why they had not earned more. They seemed to have changed their objective: from maximising their profit to explaining why they couldn’t, which change was not observed in the laboratory. Monetary rewards prevented subjects from setting their own goal by themselves and made them play seriously; though it may not be the case in every economic experiment.

  37. Differences between the classroom and the laboratory … …

  38. Human subjects can (cannot but) jump out of the system. • They move their viewpoint to make decisions so that they can make better decisions; which process is realised by dynamic brain activities. • They do not limit their inference within the system; they do meta-thinking to make decisions. • They change (find or create) new objectives if they think the original ones are not interesting or too difficult to be realised.

  39. references [1] Allais, Maurice (1953): ''Le comportement de l’homme rationel devant le risque, critique des postulates et axiomes de l’ecole americaine'', in conometrica, vol. 21, pp. 503-546. [2] Barron, Greg & Ido Erev (2003): ''Small feedback-based decisions and their limited correspondence to description-based decisions'', in Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, vol. 16, pp. 215-233.  [3] Buckner, Randy L. & Daniel C. Carroll (2007): ''Self-projection and the Brain'', in Trends in Cognitive Sciences, vol. 11, pp.49-57. [4] Camerer, Colin F. & George Loewenstein & Drazen Prelec (2005): ''Neuroeconomics: How neuroscience can inform economics'', in Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 43 (no. 1), pp. 9-64.  [5] Frederick, Shane & George Loewenstein & Ted O'Donoghue (2002): ''Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review'', in Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 40 (June), pp. 351-401.  [6] Glimcher, Paul W. (2003): ''Decisions, Uncertainty, and the Brain : The Science of Neuroeconomics'', MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA; 宮下英三【訳】(2008): 『神経経済学入門---不確実な状況で脳はどう意思決定するのか』, 生産性出版. 

  40. references [7] Gul, Faruk & Wolfgang Pesendorfer (2005): “The Case for Mindless Economics”, http://www.princeton.edu/˜pesendor/mindless.pdf. [8] Hertwig, R. & Greg Barron & E. Weber & Ido Erev (2004):“Decisions from experience and the weighting of rare events”, in Psychological Science vol.15, pp. 534-539. [9] Hofstadter, Douglas R. (1979, Escher, Bach: an Eternal Golden Braid, Basic Books, New York, USA; 野崎昭弘・はやしはじめ・柳瀬尚紀【訳】(1985): 『ゲーデル, エッシャー, バッハ—あるいは不思議の環』, 白揚社. [10] Hsu, Ming & Meghana Bhatt & Ralph Adolphs & Daniel Tranel & Colin F. Camerer (2005): “Neural Systems Responding to Degrees of Uncertainty in Human Decision-Making”, in Science, vol. 310, pp.1680-1683. [11] Kable, Joseph W. & Paul W. Glimcher (2007): “The Neural Correlates of Subjective Value During Intertemporal Choice”, in Nature NeuroScience, vol. 10(12), pp.1625-1633. [12] Kelman, Mark & Yuval Rottenstreich & Amos Tversky (1996): “Context-Dependence in Legal Decision Making”, in Journal of Legal Studies, vol. 25, issue 2, pp. 287-318. [13] Laibson, David (1997): “Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting”, in Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 112, pp. 443-477. [14] Logothetis, Nikos K. (2008): “What we can do and what we cannot do with fMRI”, in Nature, vol. 453, pp. 869-878.

  41. references [15] McClure, Samuel M & David I. Laibson & George Loewenstein & Jonathan D. Cohen (2004): “Separate Neural Systems Value Immediate and Delayed Monetary Rewards”, in Science, vol. 306, pp.503-507. [16] Moreno, Jonathan D. (2005): Mind Wars: Brain Research and National Defense, Dana Press, New York, USA; 久保田競【監訳】(2008): 『マインド・ウォーズ 操作される脳』, アスキー・メディアワークス角川グループパブリッシング. [17] 奥田次郎(2008): 「未来への予見に携わる脳神経ネットワーク」, 『玉川大学脳科学研究所紀要』, 第1 号, pp. 13-23. [18] Pasinetti, Luigi, L. (1981): Structural Change and Economic Growth: a theoretical essay on the dynamics of the wealth of nations, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK; 大塚勇一郎・渡会勝義【訳】(1983): 『構造変化と経済成長—諸国民の富の動学に関する理論的エッセイ』, 日本評論社. [19] Rubinstein, Ariel (2006): “ Discussion of “Behavioral Economics”: “Behavioral Economics” (Colin Camerer) and “Incentives and Self-Control” (Ted O’Donoghue and Matthew Rubin)”, in Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Ninth World Congress. Volume 2 (Econometric Society Monographs, no. 42) edited by Richard Blundell & Whitney K. Newey & Torsten Persson, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge and New York: pp. 246-54. [20] Samuelson, Paul, A. (1947): Foundation of Economic Analysis, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass.; 佐藤隆三【訳】(1967): 『経済分析の基礎』, 勁草書房.

  42. references [21] Shafir, Sharoni & Taly Reich & Erez Tsur & IdoErev & Arnon Lotem (2008): “Perceptual accuracy and conflicting effects of certainty on risk-taking behaviour”, in Nature, vol. 453, pp. 917-921. [22] Smith, Vernon L. (1982): “Microeconomic Systems as an Experimental Science”, in American Economic Review, vol. 66, pp. 274-279. [23] Weber, Bethany J. & Scott A. Huettel (2008): ‘The neural substrates of probabilistic and intertemporal decision making”, in Brain Research, doi: 10.1016/j.brainres.2008.07.105. [24] Yasugi, Mariko & Sobei H. Oda (2002): “A Note on the Wise Girls Puzzle”, in Economic Theory, vol. 19 (no. 1), pp. 145-156. [25] Yasugi, Mariko & Sobei H. Oda (2003): “Notes on Bounded Rationality”, in Scientiae Mathematicae Japonicae, vol. 57 (no. 1), pp. 83-92.

  43. International Conference How and why economists and philosophers do experiments: dialogue between Experimental economics and experimental philosophy Kyoto Sangyo University, Kyoto, Japan
27-28 March 2010

More Related