110 likes | 220 Views
Comments on Bordo and Landon-Lane. Stephen Broadberry (University of Warwick). Policy lessons from 1930s applied during current crisis. BLL compare the 1930s and 2007/08 crises through the prism of bank failures End on pessimistic note, but perhaps too pessimistic?
E N D
Comments on Bordo and Landon-Lane Stephen Broadberry (University of Warwick)
Policy lessons from 1930s applied during current crisis • BLL compare the 1930s and 2007/08 crises through the prism of bank failures • End on pessimistic note, but perhaps too pessimistic? • Nearly 80 years elapsed between the two crises • Policy response surely much more successful in current crisis (at least so far) than in 1930s • Policy makers do seem to have learned the important lessons of the 1930s, even if scholars continue to debate the precise details
Policy lessons from 1930s applied during current crisis • Fed prevented monetary contraction (Friedman/Schwartz analysis) • Fed prevented credit markets seizing up (Bernanke) • Fed bailed out insolvent banks (Calomiris/Mason). • Expansionary fiscal policy adopted to prevent collapse of real demand (Temin, Romer) • International co-operation perhaps imperfect, but surely better than in 1930s (Eichengreen)
Links between variables in VAR analysis and policy lessons • Bank failures/suspensions due to illiquidity: Friedman/Schwartz see bank failures as “contagion of fear” • Bank failures due to insolvency: White, Calomiris & Mason emphasise insolvency e.g. bank failures in agricultural regions in response to declining agricultural prices
Variables and links to policy • Money stock: Friedman & Schwartz criticise Fed for allowing contraction of money stock • Quality spread: Bernanke emphasises importance of contraction of credit • Change in unemployment (real aggregate shocks): Temin, Romer emphasise collapse in private consumption, which could have been offset by expansionary fiscal policy
Explaining bank failures • BLL focus on the issue of whether bank failures were caused by illiquidity or insolvency shocks • Impulse response functions suggest illiquidity shocks more important than insolvency shocks in explaining bank failures/suspensions
BLL on bank failures • Historical decompositions indicate that illiquidity shocks more important in 1930 and 1931 crises, but insolvency shocks more important in 1933 • This is exactly OPPOSITE conclusion to Calomiris and Mason, who stress role of insolvency in 1930 and 1931 but suggest a role for illiquidity in 1933
BLL on bank failures • BLL critical of micro studies on grounds that cannot see common factors driving local and regional bank failures, that may have been national in scope • But results of VAR analysis depend on identifying assumptions. Most importantly, illiquidity failure series is ordered before insolvency failure series
BLL on bank failures • Justification for this is that illiquidity shock can cause contemporaneous failure of otherwise solvent banks, but insolvency shock can cause bank run only with a lag. • But is this true with asymmetric information and monthly data? • Sensitivity analysis conducted for some orderings, but not this one
Other results for total bank failures • Money shocks mattered, as suggested by Friedman & Schwartz, but not as much as illiquidity or insolvency shocks • Real aggregate shocks relatively unimportant • Quality spread more important than real aggregate shocks, but less important than money shocks
Interpretation • These interpretations are based on forecast error decompositions for total bank failures. • How about forecast error decomposition for change in unemployment? • Impulse response functions for change in unemployment shown in appendix • Seem to get bigger effect from insolvency shocks than from illiquidity shocks