1 / 0

Bubbles in the Lab and Double oral auction

Bubbles in the Lab and Double oral auction. Rosemarie Nagel ICREA-UPF-BGSE Barcelona, Spain Visiting NYU Three Day Mini Course on Experimental Economics Columbia University Febr . 15-17. 2013. Definition.

bella
Download Presentation

Bubbles in the Lab and Double oral auction

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Bubbles in the Lab andDouble oral auction

    Rosemarie Nagel ICREA-UPF-BGSE Barcelona, Spain Visiting NYU Three Day Mini Course on Experimental Economics Columbia University Febr. 15-17. 2013
  2. Definition “A bubble may be defined loosely as a sharp rise the price of an asset …, with the initial rise generating expectations of further rises and attracting new buyers – generally speculators interested in profits from trading in the asset rather than its use or earning capacity.” -- Charles Kindleberger, The New Palgrave
  3. Can bubbles persist? Keynes (1936) “It might have been supposed that competition between expert professionals, possessing judgment and knowledge beyond that of the average private investor, would correct the vagaries of the ignorant individual left to himself.” Fama (1965) “If there are many sophisticated traders in the market, they may cause these “bubbles” to burst before they really get under way.”
  4. Why a lab experiment? Too many unknowns in the real world Control of important variables: Here: Fundamental values (at least known to the experimenter) Borrowing constraints are the same for all Time horizon the same for all Experience level of subjects can be made the same (repetition of the same market) Controlled centralized market: here call market Control of reason to buy/sell. In contrast e.g. in housing market, need for a house
  5. Creating a bubble experiment The experiment we ran in class on today closely resembles many previous experiments run by researchers. A single Call Market is run for a known finite number of rounds. Traders are allowed to buy and sell, raising the possibility of speculation. The asset being sold is typically a risky security that pays a dividend in each round. If individuals are risk neutral, the price should be a constant over time. If individuals are risk adverse, prices should be bounded above by the expected value line. Ex ante, most economists would expect to see little trading in a market like this. However, in fact we typically see frenzied trading. Economists also would expect to see prices at or below the expected value. In fact, we often observe large bubbles – persistent pricing of the security above its fundamental value. It has been argued that such bubbles are also a feature of real world security markets. It is hoped that if we can understand how bubbles form in the laboratory, we can also understand how they form (and can be prevented) in real world financial markets.
  6. Market institutionCall market First period behavior
  7. What is the theory? What should you bid according to theory? What theory? Fundamental Value: F Data Parameters: Interest (i) for cash holding: 10% random dividend (D) for shares: $0.4; prob 0.4 or $1; 0.6=> EV:0.7 Redemption value of $7 at the end Everyone holds 6 shares and $50. Being indifferent between holding shares and money: F: D/i=0.7/0.10=7 because 0.1P=0.7 (P price to pay for share). What is the fundamental value in each period if there is only dividend of 0.7 and no interest and no redemption value?
  8. Here you also see the fundamental value in each period
  9. Data set of another group
  10. Doubling the interest rate and the dividend
  11. What is the reason for bubbles in these experiments What was the best strategy in our experiment What did the person with the worst strategy do What are the fundamental values in this experiment
  12. Bubbles in the Laboratory?: Non-rational bubbles Smith Suchaneck and Williams (SSW, Ecmta 1988) experimental design reliably generates asset price bubbles and crashes in a .nite horizon economy, thus ruling out rational bubble stories. T trading periods (typically T = 15) and 9-12 inexperienced subjects. Each subject is initially endowed with various amount of cash and assets. Assets are long-lived (T periods). Endowments, are ex-ante identical in expected value -there is no reason for trade! In each trading period, agents are free to buy or sell the asset. Trade takes place via a double auction, and bids and asks must obey standard improvement rules. For each unit of the asset held at the end of a trading period, the asset owner earns a dividend payment which is a uniform draw from a known distribution and has mean d. It is public knowledge that the fundamental value of an asset at the start of period t is given by:
  13. Dufwenberg et al. AER 2005 6 subjects play 10 periods of one market game; the same market game with the same subjects is repeated again twice In the fourth game 2 or 4 subjects are replaced by inexperienced subjects Design: 2 or 4 new subjects Replacing old subjects
  14. Lei, Noussair, and Plott – Research Question “Two possible explanations for the occurrence of bubbles are the “speculative hypothesis” and the “active participation hypothesis.” In the first, traders are hoping to take advantage of irrational individuals or other speculators to make a large profit through capital gains. In other words, they are market timing. As the end of the market approaches, the bubble inevitably collapses. (This hypothesis does not require the presence of irrational traders to generate a bubble. All that is needed is a failure of common knowledge of rationality. Think about the relationship between this and Nagel’s guessing game that we studied earlier this semester.) The second hypothesis focuses on the methodology. In most bubble experiments, the only activity available to subjects is trading. To the extent that the protocols encourage participation, subjects make unprofitable trades just to be doing something. In other words, bubbles are a subtle type of demand induced effect. Lei et al aim to test these two hypotheses, separately and in conjunction. “ And they find that bubbles still exist.
  15. Lei et al. (Ecmta 2001)Explore the boredom/experimenter demand hypothesis They consider two main treatment variables. No-Spec treatment: Buyers and Sellers have distinct roles. In particular, a buyer cannot resell his asset later in a 2-minute trading period at a higher price. This tests the greater-fool hypothesis that speculation is driving the results. Two-Market treatment: Two markets operate simultaneously. One is for a one-period asset Y; holders of this asset sell it to buyers in fixed roles. The other market is the standard 15-period asset of the laboratory bubble design; this asset could be traded (bought and sold) by all subjects. Main finding, neither treatment completely eliminates bubbles and crashes. Trading volume is much lower in the two-market treatment as compared with the standard one-market case.
  16. Lei et al. (Ecmta 2001) Lei et al..s findings NoSpec/Spec illustrated
  17. Result Substantial bubbles are observed in the no-spec treatment, indicating that speculators are not needed for bubbles to form. The presence of sales that could not possibly be profitable (buying above the maximum possible dividend payoff or selling below the minimum possible dividend payoff) as well as excess volume indicate systematic errors in decision making.
  18. Conclusion It is possible to create bubbles in the lab even if fundamental values (FV) are calculable. However, most subjects do not know how to calculate them in the beginning. Experience, precise knowledge about FV and common knowledge about it (e.g. all have the same experience level and it is known to all subjects etc.) helps avoid bubbles. Experiments make comparative statics (comparing different parameter constellation) very easy The beauty contest game is an excellent tool to demonstrate behavior when there is lack of rationality and common knowledge of rationality. The behavior can be structured by the so called level k model which includes heterogeneous types from random behavior, best reply to random (level 1), best reply to level 1…etc. until rational expectation (equilibrium play). The stock market is containing aspects of the beauty contest game as first pointed out by Keynes, as one has to form believes about the behavior of the others which translates into price forecasting.
  19. Double oral auction (DOA)one of the beginnings of experimental economics by Vernon Smith (1962) V. Smith participated in a class room experiment in Chamberlin’s graduate class Buyers and sellers with induced values Buyers and sellers found privately a match by walking around Behavior did not converge to equilibrium Many years later Smith constructed the double oral auction Side remark: our intro econ course in UPF teaches the basic concepts of competitive markets (with taxes, externalities, monopoly, minimum labor wages etc) in connection with the DOA in experiments and the theory. The effect is that students much deeper understand the underlying theory and its success and failures..
  20. Double oral auction Induced reservation values for buyers and costs for sellers for a fictitious good Buyers put oral bits and sellers oral asks which are recorded on the Board, computer screen New bids >last posted bid; new asks < last posted ask If there is a match, i.e. a posted bid is higher than a posted ask then there is a match between the seller and buyer of this bid and ask: make a trade at a price between bid and ask.
  21. Experimental implementation vs theory Incomplete information of demand and supply function by market participants No auctioneer Few buyers and sellers
  22. Research Question Smith’s experiments were designed to study the neo-classical theory of competitive markets. This is the simple model of supply and demand curves that every economics student learns in the first few lecture of principles. In spite of the importance of the competitive model to economics, there was little direct evidence prior to Smith’s work that the theory actually would work. Field data is too dynamic to see if equilibrium is being achieved. Chamberlin’s (1948) earlier work using a decentralized market mechanism found that generally the prices were too low and the volumes too high as compared to competitive equilibrium predictions. Smith’s experiments were designed to give the theory its best chance to work – this reflects a desire to establish if there were any cases were the market would equilibrate as predicted by the theory. Smith was interested in studying what configurations of supply and demand were most (or least) likely to lead to equilibrium, and was also interested in the dynamics that led to equilibrium This and the following slides are taken from the web “smithoverhead”
  23. Initial Hypotheses Markets are expected to converge to the competitive equilibrium. According to the “Walrasian” hypothesis, this convergence should be faster when there is larger excess demand (or supply). So, for example, convergence should be faster in Test 2 than in Test 3. The “excess rent” hypothesis focuses on unrealizable profits at a price – the higher these are, the faster prices should adjust. [Historically, this has not been an important hypothesis.] Allowing more experience should speed up convergence, while changing market institutions should slow convergence.
  24. Summary of Sessions The sessions focus primarily on the effect of vary the shape of the supply and demand curves. Some attention is also paid to the effect of changing market institutions and making traders more experienced.. Test 1: Basic supply and demand Tests 2 and 3: Varies steepness of supply and demand curves without changing equilibrium price. This allows Smith to study the process that leads to equilibrium. Test 4: Flat supply curve. This leaves no surplus for the sellers. It is interesting to think of this in light of much later experiments on equity in market games. Test 5: Studies the effect of an increase in demand. Given that subjects don’t know how demand has changed, you might expect this to disrupt convergence. Test 6: Equilibrium gives a very large surplus to the sellers by using a supply curve that goes vertical. Once again, this is interesting in light of the later experiments on market games. Test 7: Very steep supply curve relative to the demand curve. Test 8: Buyers were not allowed to make bids in early periods. This was supposed to simulate retail markets. The question is whether this prevents convergence to equilibrium. Test 9 and 10: Each individual is allowed to make two transactions, doubling the amount of experience received. This is expected to speed convergence.
  25. Results – Convergence to Equilibrium The double oral auctions tend to converge strongly towards equilibrium and achieve high levels of efficiency. For example, the results for Test 1 are shown top right. This is true even when either demand or supply shifts over time. See Test 5 results, bottom right. This is a very basic result, but is the most important result in the paper. Competitive market equilibrium is a central concept in economic theory, but generally can’t be observed in the field. These results prove that competitive equilibrium can work (but not that it must work).
  26. Results – Uneven Splits of Surplus Test 4 and Test 7 both feature uneven (predicted) splits of the total surplus between buyers and sellers. These sessions are among the worst in terms of convergence to equilibrium. Test 4 prices were consistently above equilibrium, giving some surplus to the sellers. Test 7, which isn’t quite as extreme as Test 4, only converges very slowly to equilibrium. Prices are consistently too low (compared to competitive equilibrium) giving some surplus to buyers. These results can be viewed as a precursor to the sorts of results on fairness that we have studied extensively.
  27. Copnvergence to equilibrium Excess rent =2 Excess rent =2 Excess rent =5 Excess rent =5 Excess rent =8 Excess rent =8
  28. Conclusions While Smith draws many conclusions from the data, the most important conclusion is the most basic one: “The most striking general characteristic of tests 1 – 3 5 – 7 9, and 10 is the remarkably strong tendency for exchange prices to approach the predicted equilibrium for each of these markets.” It must be remembered that Smith designed his experiments to give the theory its best chance. These experiments don’t establish that in general the theory of competitive equilibrium will have much predictive power. On a more general level, this paper played an important role in illustrating how controlled laboratory experiments let economists understand phenomena and theories that were hard to observe in the field. In the field, one never knows what the underlying supply and demand curves are, so you can never truly know that the competitive equilibrium has been achieved. In the lab, you can directly observe the emergence of equilibrium.
  29. Further Research on Markets Smith’s general results on convergence have been replicated many times. DOA markets are remarkably good at converging to equilibrium under a wide variety of circumstances. This remains true even if supply and demand curves are shifting (although random shifts do worsen convergence). Convergence can be quite sensitive to market institutions. Seemingly small changes in the rules for queuing can substantially affect the speed of convergence. Larger changes in the institutions such as using a posted price market can greatly slow convergence, even leading to non-convergence in some cases. Market power has mixed effects on convergence to equilibrium. Holt, Langan, and Villamil (1986) find prices that are significantly above equilibrium when sellers have market power, but others have found little effect in DOA markets. More generally, the impact of market power is going to depend on the game being played. When a single individual can easily manipulate market prices or when institutions reduce competition among sellers, departures from equilibrium are more likely. Game theory does a fairly good job of predicting when departures from equilibrium are likely, although it does a poor job of predicting the size of these departures.
More Related