260 likes | 356 Views
VC v. VCG: Inapproximability of Combinatorial Auctions via Generalizations of the VC Dimension. Michael Schapira Yale University and UC Berkeley. Joint work with Christos Papadimitriou and Yaron Singer (2008) and Elchanan Mossel, Christos Papadimitriou and Yaron Singer (2009).
E N D
VC v. VCG: Inapproximability of Combinatorial Auctions via Generalizations of the VC Dimension Michael Schapira Yale University and UC Berkeley Joint work with Christos Papadimitriou and Yaron Singer (2008) and Elchanan Mossel, Christos Papadimitriou and Yaron Singer (2009)
Auctions: Different Concerns computational efficiency • Computational concerns: • bounded computational resources • optimization • … • Economic concerns: • truthful behaviour • fairness • … incentive-compatibility
Algorithmic Mechanism Design • Can these different desiderata coexist? • The central problem in Algorithmic Mechanism Design[Nisan-Ronen]
Illustration: Restricted Combinatorial Auctions • A set of m items for sale {1,…m}. • n bidders {1,…,n}. Each bidder i has an additive valuation with a spending constraint vi. • per-item values ai1,…,aim • “maximum spending” value bi • For every bundle S, vi(S)=min {S j in S aij , bi}, • Goal: find a partition of the items between the bidders S1,…,Sn such that social welfare Si vi(Si) is maximized
What Do We Want? • Quality of the solution:As close to the optimum as possible. • Computationally tractable:Polynomial running time (in n and m). • Truthful:Motivate (via payments) agents to report their true values. • The utility of each user is ui = vi(S) – pi • Solution concepts: dominant strategies, ex-post Nash.
State of the Art • Easy from an economic perspective. • VCG! • Easy to solve computationally. • NP-hard (even for n=2) [Lehmann-Lehmann-Nisan] but… • We can get arbitrarily close to the optimum for any constant n (PTAS)! [Andelman-Mansour] • Can both be achieved simultaneously?
Huge Gap! ? non-truthful:get arbitrarilyclose to opt. truthful: 1/n-appx mechanism
Truthfulness and Computation Clash: Combinatorial Public Projects Problem (CPPP) • Orthogonal to combinatorial auctions (elections, overlay networks). • Easy from a purely economic perspective (VCG), and from a purely computational perspective (in APX). • Theorem (Informal) [Papadimitriou-S-Singer]:No truthful and computationally-efficient mechanism for CPPP obtains a constant approximation ratio.
(Characterization of truthful mechanisms, based on Roberts’ Theorem) (VC dimension) Combinatorial Public Projects:The Proof mechanism design Complexity theory (the embedding of NP-hard problems) combinatorics
(Characterization of truthful mechanisms, based on Roberts’ Theorem) consider a specific class of mechanisms(VCG-based). generalize the VC dimension to handle partitions of a universe. (VC dimension) What About Combinatorial Auctions? mechanism design Complexity theory (the embedding of NP-hard problems) combinatorics
VCG-Based Mechanisms • VCG-based = Maximal-In-Range (MIR). • MIR mechanisms provide the best known (deterministic) approximations for a large variety of problems: • Combinatorial auctions (general, subadditive, submodular). • Multi-unit auctions. • Unrelated machine scheduling. • In fact, sometimes MIR is all you can do. [Roberts, Lavi-Mu’alem-Nisan, Dobzinski-Sundararajan, Papadimitriou-S-Singer]
RM allpartitions Maximal-In-Range Mechanisms • A mechanism M is MIR (= VCG-based) if: • There’s a fixed subset RM of the possible outcomes (allocations of the m items between the n bidders) = “M’s range”. • For every valuation profile (v1,…vn) M outputs the optimal partition in RM. • Example: The trivial (1/n-appx.) mechanism • Bundle all items together. • Allocated them to the highest bidder. • Fact: MIR mechanisms are truthful (VCG…).
Can We Do Better Than the Trivial MIR Mechanism? • Can we choose RM such that • the optimum in RM always provides a constant approximation to the global optimum. • optimizing over RM can be done in a computationally-efficient manner. • Not for the more general class of submodular valuations! [Dobzinski-Nisan] • But… the “input” there is assumed to be exponentially large! (exp. communication) • What about succinctly-described valuations? • No computational-complexity results are known!
The Case of 2 Bidders • Not trivial even for n=2! • We shall focus on this case. • Let us first consider the (more easy) allocate-all-items case. • all outcomes in RM do not leave any item unallocated. • Theorem: No computationally-efficient MIR mechanism M obtains an appx-ratio of ½+e in the allocate-all-items case. • unless NP has polynomial size circuits.
Proof • Let M be a MIR mechanism for the 2-bidder case. • Assume, by contradiction, that M obtains an appx-ratio of (1/2+e). • We shall prove that optimizing over RM implicitly means solving an NP-hard problem.
Proof (intuition) Mechanism M 4 1 3 5 2 4 1 3 5 2 RM 4 1 3 5 2 4 1 3 5 2 M is (implicitly)optimally solvinga 2-item auction items 4 1 3 5 2
Proof • So, we wish to prove the existence of a subset of items E that is “shattered” by M’s range (RM). • “Embed” a smaller auction in E. • Not too small! (|E| ≥ ma) • VC dimension!
Proof • Lemma: If a MIR mechanism M obtains an appx-ratio of ½+e in the allocate-all-items case then |RM| ≥ 2gm (for some constant g>0). • Proof by probabilistic construction. • Corollary: Bidder 1 can be assigned at least 2gm different subsets of items by M. • Denote this collection of subsets by RM,1
Proof • The Sauer-Shelah Lemma: Let R be a collection of subsets of a universe U. Then, there exists a subset E of U such that: • R’s projection on E is 2E. • |E| ≥W( log(|R|)/log(|U|) ). • Corollary (set R=RM,1): There is a subset of items E, |E| ≥ ma, s.t. bidder 1 can be assigned all subsets of E in M. • Corollary: All partitions of E are induced by RM. • Because all items are allocated.
Proof • We can now conclude that if M optimizes over its range then it is optimally solving an identical auction with ma items. • An NP-hard task. • A non-uniform reduction. • We do not know how to find E in polynomial time. • So… No computationally-efficient MIR mechanism M obtains an appx-ratio of ½+e in the allocate-all-items case (unless NP has polynomial size circuits). QED
Getting Rid of the Allocate-All-Items Assumption • Not trivial! • If we just allocate unallocated items arbitrarily we might lose the MIR property! • Our approach: Generalizing the VC dimension. • Of independent interest.
An Analogue of the Sauer-Shelah Lemma • Definition: A partition of a universe is a pair of disjoint subsets of the universe. • Does not necessarily exhaust the universe! • Definition: Two partitions, (T1,T2) and (T’1,T’2) , are said to be b-far (or at distance b) if |T1U T’2| + |T’1U T2| ≥ b.
An Analogue of the Sauer-Shelah Lemma • Lemma: Let d> 0 be some constant. Let R be a collection of partitions of a universe U, such that every two partitions in R are d|U|-far. Then, there exists a subset E of U such that: • R’s projection on E is all partitions of E. • |E| ≥ W( log(|R|)/log(|U|) ).
A Lower Bound • Theorem: For any MIR mechanism M that obtains an appx-ratio of ¾ + e, there exists some R RM such that • R is exponential in m. • Every two partitions in R are dm-far (for some constant d>0) • Theorem: No computationally-efficient MIR mechanism M obtains an appx-ratio of ¾+e. • unless NP has polynomial size circuits.
Directions for Future Research • A recent result [Buchfuhrer-Umans]: For any constant n, no MIR mechanism M obtains an appx-ratio of 1/n+e (unless NP has polynomial size circuits). • Tight for all constant n’s. • Non-constant n’s? • Other classes of valuation functions. • Characterizing truthful mechanisms for combinatorial auctions. • Relaxing the computational assumption. • Many intriguing questions regarding the VC dimension of partitions.