340 likes | 425 Views
Naureen Karachiwalla, University of Oxford Albert Park, HKUST. Promotion Incentives in the Public Sector: Evidence from Chinese Schools. Motivations. Teachers are central to the learning process Often undermotivated in developing countries Exclusive focus on incentive pay (bonuses)
E N D
Naureen Karachiwalla, University of Oxford Albert Park, HKUST Promotion Incentives in the Public Sector: Evidence from Chinese Schools
Motivations • Teachers are central to the learning process • Often undermotivated in developing countries • Exclusive focus on incentive pay (bonuses) • China ideal case to study use of promotions to provide incentives—sophisticated system, good performance • Incentives for civil servants, puzzle of governance and rapid growth in China? • Empirical evidence on promotion incentives • Previous evidence mostly on use of incentives (by studying wage patterns) in US companies • Little direct evidence on effort/performance (Gibbs, 1995; Campbell 2008, Kwon 2006)
Outline • Motivations • Promotion of teachers in China • Data • Model of Promotions as Incentives • Empirical model • Results • Conclusion
Promotion of Teachers in China • Four ranks in both primary and middle school • To apply for a promotion, need: • To wait a certain number of years (depending on education) • Favourable annual evaluation scores (one ‘excellent’ or two ‘good’) in the last 5 years • Promotion depends on the number of spaces available in a township • Wages are higher at higher rank levels
Teacher evaluations • Annual evaluations on a four point scale: excellent, good, pass, fail. Set proportions. • Based on four criteria: student test scores, attendance, preparation and ‘attitude’. Committee chooses weights. • Classroom observation, questionnaires to teachers and students, principal reports. Points for each component. • Points added, teachers are ranked. Top 10% get ‘excellent’, next 10% get ‘good’ scores. Rest get a ‘pass’. • Results of ‘excellent’ and ‘good’ evaluation scores announced at annual meetings
Data • Gansu Survey of Children and Families (GSCF), focussed on rural schools • 3 waves, we use 2007. Child, teacher, principal etc. • Sampled 100 villages in 42 townships in 20 counties • Sampled the main primary and middle school in each village • Sample of 2,350 teachers
Literature – Theory • Promotions as tournaments, Lazear and Rosen (1981). Wage gap that can induce first best effort exists. • Macleod and Malcolmson (1988) model of skill and effort as private information. Employees sort into ranks according to ability. • Fairburn and Malcolmson (1994) sorting into different jobs. Promotions can be made incentive compatible. • Gibbs (1989) multi-person tournaments with heterogeneous competitors. Predictions on ability, number of competitors, time after promotion, beliefs on ability etc.
Model of Promotions as Incentives • School offers promotions, teachers hired in lowest rank, n teachers compete for k promotion slots at each rank level • School offers ΔEU (W2 - W1)*tenure after promotion • Teachers have different skill, s with B(s) and b(s), E(s)=0 • Cost of effort (e) is C(e) where C’ , C’’ >0 • p(e, s, e) is probability of promotion
Model of Promotions as Incentives • Teacher solves: • First order condition: • dp/de is marginal probability of promotion (MPE)
Model of Promotions as Incentives • qi = si + ei + πi where πi = εi + μ, CDF R(q) PDF r(q) • E(πi)=E(εi)=E(μ)=0, CDF F(ε), PDF f(ε) • Probability teacher i beats teacher g: pr(qi > qg) = pr(ei + si + εi + μ > eg + sg + εg + μ) = pr(eg + sg + εg + < ei + si + εi) = R(ei + si + εi) • Probability of promotion:
Predictions • Incentives higher with higher wage increases when promoted • Incentives decline with age • Incentive highest when skill percentile = 1 – p*, and declines with distance from 1-p* • When n increases but p* stays the same, incentives increase for those close with skill percentile close to 1 - p* (and decrease for those with very high or very low skill)
Multiperiod Model • Teachers have careers of T periods, eligible for promotion in year t = X • Probability of promotion, pt is based on performance in past 5 years • Normalize per period utility before promotion to zero, define Uh > 0 utility from wages after promotion • In year j, lifetime expected discounted utility is: • Prior belief on skill, s1, 1/N ≤ s1 ≤ 1. True relative rank s. • Teachers update beliefs on skill rank st , adjust st downward when passed over for promotion
More Predictions • Predictions on teacher performance over time • If t ≤ X – 5 effort is zero • Effort is increasing from t=X – 4 to X • Teachers update beliefs on s based on whether or not they are promoted. When teachers are not promoted, s is revised downwards, effort is decreasing for every year of non-promotion
Empirical Specification • From the one-period model’s FOC: • Estimate as: • We will estimate with fixed effects so w and p will drop out. We will also add in the time dimension.
Empirical specification • ev = evaluation scores for t = 2003, 2004, 2005, 2006 • a = ability index, dummies for top and bottom 10% • n = number of teachers, also interacted with ability in top and bottom 10% • w = fixed effect • D – dummies for: • t = X – 5 or greater • t = X – 4, t = X – 3, t = X – 2, t = X – 1 , t=X • t > after half the other teachers are promoted (dummies from one to ten years after half of colleagues are promoted)
Empirical results • Evaluation scores increase with higher expected wage increases • Evaluation scores increase in the years preceding promotion eligibility and decrease after not being promoted (inverted U) or reaching the highest rank • Evaluation scores increase with competition (number of teachers) for those in the middle of the skill distribution but do not for those in the tails of the skill distribution • Promotion probability positively affected by high evaluation scores
Results – X-5 to X X-5 X-4 X-3 X-2 X-1 X
Primary High Theory predicts no effort incentive after achieving highest rank, decline suggests older teachers slowing down (rising cost of effort?)
Evaluations as a proxy for effort • One could argue that the evaluation scores capture both ability and effort • However, the use of the fixed effect and the ability index mitigate this problem • A regression was also run of the probability of obtaining an ‘excellent’ or ‘good’ evaluation score on measures of teacher time use • This was done for 2006 only since that is what we have data on • Coefficient on number of hours (spent with students, preparing lesson plans, marking homework etc.) is positive and significant
Robustness • What if principals are just awarding high scores to teachers who are nearing eligibility for promotion? • Again, evaluation scores are related to time use • Restricted the sample to counties that have high correlations between time use and evaluation scores and the effect remains • Ranks strongly predict test scores (other studies) • Or, teachers could be learning and that would also produce an upward trend pre-eligibility • The teachers in the sample have already been teaching for many years (average experience is 12 years)
Conclusion • Effort responds to promotion incentives • Implications for design • Optimal contest size and promotion rate? • Incentivizing teachers falling behind • Combining pay for performance (within-rank incentives) with promotion incentives (happening in China!)