410 likes | 532 Views
Rescuing Clinical Trial Data For Economic Evaluation. Paul Kind, Ph.D. Jan van Busschbach, Ph.D. Frank de Charro, Ph.D. Overview of the workshop. Frank de Charro: Introduction Jan van Busschbach: How to shoot straight at the goal Paul Kind: How to score with more subtle combinations.
E N D
Rescuing Clinical Trial Data For Economic Evaluation Paul Kind, Ph.D. Jan van Busschbach, Ph.D. Frank de Charro, Ph.D.
Overview of the workshop • Frank de Charro: Introduction • Jan van Busschbach: How to shoot straight at the goal • Paul Kind: How to score with more subtle combinations
The problem • Many clinical studies do not generate outcomes data that are suitable for economic evaluation • They may include condition-specific measures but these were generally not designed for the type of analysis required • Such studies may include measures of health-related quality of life as secondary endpoints
Economic evaluation • Cost Effectiveness Analysis Measure ofeffectiveness can be anything as long as scaling properties are ok • Cost Utility Analysis Measure of effectivenss: QALYs
EQ-5D: Descriptive System • Classification of health states using 5 dimensions • mobility • self care • usual activity • pain / discomfort • anxiety / depression • 3 problem levels for each (none / some / extreme) • defines a total of 35 • = 243 health states Pain Self-care Mood Health state Mobility Usual activities
State A : 1 1 2 2 3 Scoring EQ-5D health states Population TTO weights State B : 1 1 3 2 2
The challenge To devise methodologies that can be used to convert outcomes data collected in clinical studies into a form that have the necessary attributes to support economic evaluation (CUA)
Clinical analysis/report Secondary data Clinical study Economic analysis / report Primary data Cost-effectiveness Cost-utility Rescuing economic analysis
A word of caution • Quality adjustment is one of the most important outcome characteristics • Indirect approaches involve uncertainty and diminish the potential to differentiate between a treatment and its alternativess • Cost effectiveness will be judged taking into account uncertainty and using probabilistic models • So crosswalks are second best but better than no coverage of utility at all
The valuation of disease-specific health states • Jan J. v. Busschbach, Ph.D. • Erasmus MC • Institute for Medical Psychology and Psychotherapy • www.busschbach.nl • Sildenafil (Viagra)
The effects of Sildenafil in terms QALY’s is complicated • QALYs are measured with standardised and validated quality of life questionnaires • EQ-5D or HUI III were not included • Not sensitive for erectile dysfunction?
Clinical outcomes • Gradations erectile dysfunction • were chosen as clinical outcomes • Measured with the IIEF • International Index of Erectile Function • Primary end points: Question 3 and 4 • Ability to attain an erection • Example: During intercourse I am sometimes able to penetrate • Ability to maintain an erection • I can almost never maintain the erection during intercourse after penetration
Clinical, disease specific outcomes Goldstein et al., N Engl J Med, 1998
How to convert clinical outcomes into QALYs ? • 2 questions 5 answer levels = 25 health states • Why not value the 25 these health states with Time Trade-Off ? • 169 subjects of the general public • Valued the 25 health states with TTO • Individual administration within groups sessions • Validation of procedure in students (group versus individual)
25 Erectile Dysfunction States • During intercourse I am sometimes able to penetrate • I can almost never maintain the erection during intercourse after penetration
Transferred clinical outcomes into QALYs On the basis of Goldstein et al., N Engl J Med, 1998
Healthy No complains Death All complains Disease specific utilities are not equal to generic utilities • Only the disutility of the specific disease is valued • Generic and specific utilities are not on the same scale • Generic top anchor: absence of any impairment • Specific top anchor: absence of specific impairment • Co morbidity might still be present
How to interpret disease specific utilities • Value of life years “traded off” in TTO differ • Healthy subject: 1 life year is 1.0 QALY • Sick subject: 1 life year is 0.5 QALY • Life years of healthy persons are more worth than those of sick • Overall health states influence disutility • 20% trade off at 1.00: disutility = 0.20 • 20% trade off at 0.80: disutility = 0.16 • 20% trade off at 0.60: disutility = 0.12 • Raw disease specific trade-off overestimated gains
Specific utilities should be corrected for average morbidity • Solution: multiplicative model • Multiply disease specific value with average value • Values have to be multiplied by average value for age group. • For instance in IPSS • male age 55-64: overall QoL utility: 0.81 • Most severe BPH: 0.87 • Male age 55-64 with most severe BPH: 0.81 x 0.87 = .7047 • Maximum gain reduces from • Raw score 1.00 - 0.87 = 0.13 • Adjust score 0.81 - 0.70 = 0.11 • 15 % reduction
Rue of thumb • Overestimated CE-ration by 15% using specific utilities • Proposed by Fryback & Lawrence, MDM 1997 • For not completely the same problem… • …for own health states, not imaginable health states
We validated the IIEF and the IPSS for the use in economic appraisal Now, IPSS and IIEF has QALY-weights Many other applications possible (health states of…) diabetic foot ulcers Advantage High sensitive disease specific measures for QALY-analysis No need for generic instrument Disadvantages Not directly compatible with generic utilities…. ± 15 % correction needed Conclusion (1)
Overestimation? • Does the focus on the disease makes the disutility to high?
Crosswalks: recalibrating Paul Kind Visiting Professor University of Uppsala, Sweden PrincipalInvestigator Outcomes Research GroupCentre for Health EconomicsUniversity of YorkEngland pk1@york.ac.uk
Recalibration – the task • Source assumed to be a clinical / condition-specific (sensitive) measure • Format • Summary score / Index • Subscale scores / dimension scores • Items (all or selected) • Target assumed to be a generic index weighted using social preferences • Task – to recalibrate source in terms of target
Recalibration strategies - direct • Derive direct estimates of social preferences for source index • May require simplification of complex descriptive system • Will have implications for time and resourcing • May conflict with instrument developer agenda
Recalibration strategies - indirect • Multiple solutions linking all or part of source instrument with the target index (directly or indirectly) Strategy A Estimate target index from A1 source index A2 sources subscales A3 source items Strategy B Estimate target dimension/levels from B1 source subscales B2 source items
Strategy A1 • 25 item condition sensitive instrument with widespread usage in its therapeutic field • Yes/no answers coded to 1/0 • All items assumed equal weight • Summary index • General population survey of circa 1,000 yielded parallel observations with EQ-5D
A mean estimated observed EQ-5D’ = 0.9696 – 0.0204* A
Issues • Number of observations across “severity” range • Subgroup impact • Age / gender • Significant factors but small effect • Regression on mean observations • Why not micro level ? • Less good fit • Tricky / messy business • May not significantly improve estimation • EQ5D’ = 0.9419 – 0.0163
Strategy A3EORTC QLQC-30 • EORTC QLQC-30 is a generic measure of health-related quality of life (HrQoL) in cancer. Version #3 consists of 28 items with a 4-category response and 2 further items (general health and quality of life) are coded on a 7-point response category scale (see selected items below). • Responses are converted into corresponding numeric scores that may be summed to produce a total score. However, QLQC-30 cannot be used in cost-effectiveness analysis because it is not standardized on a value scale where full health = 1 and dead = 0.
Data • Baseline observations from a previously reported study of 177 patients with pancreatic cancer were available for analysis. HrQoL in these patients had been assessed by self-report using both the QLQ-C30 and EQ-5D measures. • Additional baseline data on patients included their Karnofsky Performance Scale rating
Methods • The first 28 QLQC-30 items were dichotomised (not at all = 0 ; quite a bit to very much = 1) and these items, together with the uncoded response to item 29 (general health) were entered in a stepwise linear regression in which EQ-5Dindex was the dependent variable.
Results • The results of this regression analysis are given in Table 1, showing that only 6 of the QLQC-30 items proved to be significant. • The r2 of 0.490 equates with levels seen in other such calibration studies. Correlation between observed EQ-5Dindex and estimated values was generally high. However, correlation between observed EQ-5Dindex and estimated value amongst female patients is higher than for male patients in the sample (r = 0.725 vs 0.662). Mean differences across all patients was -0.001 • Figure 1 shows the scatterplot of observed EQ-5D and the value derived for each patient using the 6-item QLQC-30 model
Figure 2 : Mean observed and estimated EQ-5Dindex values for categories of Karnofsky Performance Scale
Have a nice walk But also Try to keep going straight if possible www.euroqol.org rabin@frg.eur.nl userinformationservice@euroqol.org