410 likes | 615 Views
UMKC Department of Economics. Professor Mathew Forstater forstaterm@umkc.edu 816-235-5862. What is Economics?. The study of the Economy—What is the Economy? How societies organize themselves to provide for their material well-being.
E N D
UMKC Department of Economics Professor Mathew Forstater forstaterm@umkc.edu 816-235-5862
What is Economics? • The study of the Economy—What is the Economy? • How societies organize themselves to provide for their material well-being. • All human communities throughout history have had to address the questions concerning material provisioning. • In order to survive, at the very least societies must combine resources to produce food to meet biological and nutritional requirements and shelter to protect against the vagaries of nature.
RESOURCES • Natural resources (“Land”) • Exhaustible resources (coal, oil) • Renewable resources (solar, wind) • Human resources (“Labor”) • Mental and physical expenditures of human energy • All labor is some combination of brain work and manual work • reproducible inputs (“capital??”) • Produced means of production
RESOURCES • Natural resources (“Land”) • Exhaustible resources (coal, oil) • Renewable resources (solar, wind)
RESOURCES • Human resources (“Labor”) • Mental and physical expenditures of human energy • All labor is some combination of brain work and manual work
RESOURCES • reproducible inputs • Produced means of production • Tools, machines
Reproducible inputs • Outputs of production process that are used as inputs in other production processes • Not necessarily “capital” • Capital can refer to financial or “money capital” (not an input, but can be used to purchase any inputs) or to industrial capital or “capital goods” • Reproducible input only becomes a capital good when it is used to produce “commodities” • Commodity: anything produced for sale in a market
PRODUCTION • Production is key to material provisioning • Not just production of “whatever” • Society must produce those goods that are sufficient to guarantee human survival • So society must decide what to produce
PRODUCTION • Often there is more than one way to produce the same good • Alternative methods of production • Which to use? • Society must decide how to produce those goods it has decided will make up the output
PRODUCTION • If society decides what to produce, how to produce it, and does so effectively, will that guarantee the continuing viability of the community, or social reproduction?
The Economic Problem • No. Society must also determine how to distribute the production in such a way as to guarantee the reproduction of the community. • The Economic problem at the most fundamental level concerns these three questions concerning production and distribution.
The Economic Problem • How, historically, have societies answered these questions of production and distribution? • Most societies, for most of human history, have addressed these questions by what we may call “tradition.”
TRADITION • In traditional societies, over long periods of time, through processes of trial and error, social institutions evolved that determined production and distribution.
Tradition—Institutions • Social rules and codes of behavior that determine: • who does what? (division of labor) • Who gets what? (distribution of the social product) • In traditional societies, often some combination of age, gender, and kinship relations
age, gender, and kinship • Young men herd large animals, women tend gardens and build the home, children take care of small animals and fetch firewood and water, elders make management decisions and settle disputes, senior elders are keepers of history and ritual.
Reciprocity: Mutual Gift Giving • From early on in life, members/families of traditional societies begin giving gifts to their neighbors, kinfolk, and others. • Giving of a gift imposes on the recipient an obligation to give back some time in the future. • Families accumulate these reciprocal obligations, which play an important role in social reproduction.
Reciprocity • Reciprocal gift relations protect against localized drought, livestock epidemics, crop failure and other localized shocks. • Family on one side of the mountain has a very good year, with more than usual livestock growth and above average crops. Giving is an economic necessity—they don’t have the labor or pasture to take care of more livestock and no refrigeration.
Reciprocity • Family on other side of the mountain needs livestock and crops because they had low rainfall or other problems, so they need the gifts to live. • The next year, the situation is reversed, and the second family reciprocates.
Traditional Institutions: Redistribution • Similar to reciprocity, but in this case crops, fish, meat, etc. are redistributed throughout the community. Sometimes takes the form of a harvest festival. • Community gathers together and eats, sings, dances, and celebrates. Members of the community pledge to continue to follow the rules of the community.
The Economic Surplus • Surplus is production above and beyond just what it takes to reproduce the society, including labor and inputs used up in production. • Suppose the society produces one good—corn—using corn seed and labor. • Suppose that they produce 10,000 bushels of corn output per year using 1,000 bushels of corn seed and 8,000 bushels of corn food to feed the population and so reproduce the labor force.
Traditional Corn Model • 10,000 bu. Corn output • 8,000 bu. Corn food (viewed as an input) • 1,000 bu. Corn seed • Inputs = 8K + 1K = 9,000 bu. • 10,000 bu. Output – 9,000 bu. Inputs = 1,000 bu. Corn Surplus • 1,000 bu. may be redistributed throughout the community, used for the harvest feast, given to ritual leaders (or anyone who does not directly produce corn), traded with neighbors, etc.
Corn Model • Suppose one year the Elders meet and one says, “I was thinking that this year we could take some of the extra corn and put it in the seed bin.” • If 100 bu. of the corn surplus were added to the seed bin and technology stayed the same, and labor/population stayed the same, then 1,100 bu. of corn seed would produce 11,000 bu. of corn output.
More inputs more output and surplus • 1,100 corn seed + 8,000 corn food = 9,100 corn inputs 11,000 corn output – 9,100 corn inputs = 1,900 corn surplus They can have the feast, add more seed, redistribute more corn food, trade it with their friends! What is happening here?
Corn model • In capitalist context: Using surplus to increase the size of the inputs is called “investment.” The higher output resulting from more inputs is called “economic growth.” Surplus would be “profits.”
Follow the Surplus • What can happen as a result of this process? • More output can support a growing population, and larger labor force. • More people can lead to territorial expansion. • Meet new peoples, intermarry, martial alliance, trade, new products, new technologies, more output and surplus, and so on.
Growth and Expansion • All these developments may lead to a situation where the old rules and institutions that used to satisfy the needs of the community no longer are capable of doing so, and new ways of organizing production and distribution are necessary. • May mean a transition from a “traditional” society to a “command” system.”
Command In tradition society, religious or cultural institutions determine production and distribution. • In a command system, political institutions determine production and distribution. Some central political authority—a Chief, Lord, King, Central Planning Board—decides ‘who does what’ and ‘who gets what’.
Command • European feudalism is a prime example of a command system. • Lords and Serfs.
Command • Slavery is another form of command. (The Enslavement of Africans to perform plantation labor in the ‘new world’ may be a special case of “capitalist slavery”).
Command Command can be a very effective way of marshalling resources— many of the great ‘public works’ projects of the ancient world were the result of a command-type system.
Command • But command can also be very brutal.
Tradition, Command, and… • The third historical system of organizing production and distribution is the market. • The market is a very curious means of organizing production and distribution. • The market appears to be millions and billions of independent decisions concerning buying and selling.
The Market • If the market was only millions and billions of independent decisions concerning buying and selling it would not have lasted a week. It must be more than that—it is a system. While markets are not perfectly orderly—there are booms and busts, crises, recessions and depressions—there is something orderly-like about a market’s systematic operation.
Market • It was to discover or uncover the rules that govern the market’s systematic operation that economics, or political economy as it was first called—came into being. • In traditional societies the economy was ‘embedded’ in cultural institutions; in command societies, the economy was ‘embedded’ in political institutions; in market societies, for the first time, a distinctly economic institution governed production and distribution. The economy became ‘dis-embedded.’
Market System • What are the institutions that govern a market’s systematic operation? • Competition…supply and demand forces…price mechanism…’higgling and haggling.’
Mixed Systems • There are no ‘pure’ systems of any type—tradition, command, and market—except some traditional societies with virtually no command or market. But most historical societies were some combination of the three. Command systems still had markets on the edges and tradition at the local level, traditional societies trade with neighbors and had some command elements.
Modern Mixed Systems • If most systems are mixed, whether they are labeled tradition, command, or market depends on the dominant way in which production and distribution are organized. • In our modern market dominated societies, there is still a good dose of tradition and command. Examples?
Command in Contemporary Society • All government production and distribution is command. Government decisions to build schools, bridges, hospitals, tanks, is production determined by command. • All taxation and redistribution (Social Security, etc.) is distribution determined by command.
Tradition in Modern Market Society • Tipping, holiday gift-giving, bonuses, do-it-yourself (gardening, auto repair, painting your house), cooperative ventures—fix your friends car, they buy pizza; unpaid housework and child-rearing; volunteerism, etc.—actually a lot of tradition! • Some say market could not exist without healthy amounts of tradition and command.
Political Economy and Economics • It was to discover or uncover the rules that govern the market’s systematic operation that economics, or political economy as it was first called—came into being. • There was not and is not one theory as to the market’s systematic operation. There are contending perspectives.
Schools of Thought • There are many schools and sub-schools of economic thought. • “Mercantilist” • “Classical Political Economy” • “Neoclassical” (often wrongly called “Classical”) • “Keynesian” (neo-, Post, New, old, etc.) • Austrian, Ecological, Anarchist, Feminist, Black Political Economy, Sraffian, Institutionalist, etc.