210 likes | 230 Views
Explore the impact of public investment on basic utilities like electricity, water, and sanitation in low-income countries. Learn about fiscal and monetary policies, alternative financing sources, and implications for economic development.
E N D
The Macroeconomics of Financing Basic Utilities for All Terry McKinley Director, International Poverty Centre “Financing Access to Basic Utilities for All” Multi-Stakeholder Consultation, Lusaka, 23-25 April 2007
Some Research Background • UNDP has supported 25 national reports on Economic Policies for Growth, Employment and Poverty Reduction since 2002 • The motivation has been to promote greater policy dialogue and provide policy alternatives on economic policies www.undp-povertycentre.org/reports.htm • Coverage: Asia-Pacific, Eastern Europe and the CIS, Middle East, and sub-Saharan Africa • Focus: a) fiscal, monetary and exchange-rate policies and b) financial liberalization, trade liberalization and privatization • UNDP has also supported a global project on “Privatization and Poverty Reduction” (most studies are in low-income countries in Africa)
The Conclusion of the Studies • Privatisation and commercialisation of public services are often not compatible in low-income countries with achieving the Millennium Development Goals • See Working Paper #22 of the International Poverty Centre: “Can Privatisation and Commercialisation of Public Services Help Achieve the MDGs: An Assessment?”www.undp-povertycentre.org • Also see the IPC Policy Research Brief #3:“Privatising Basic Utilities in Sub-Saharan Africa: the MDG Impact” and the ensuing debate in One Pagers • Central Questions: How will access to public services—such as water, sanitation and electricity—be financed? What are the Macroeconomic Implications?
Access to Electricity: The Need for Public Investment • How to reach households without electricity? • Two-thirds of households in Africa—83% in rural areas? • 59% of households in South Asia—70% in rural areas? • We have to dramatically ‘scale up’ public investment in order to expand the electrical grid or provide alternative cheaper sources of energy • Costing the public investment needed to reach the MDGs has provided a stronger impetus for a change in strategy • A greater need for Economic Policies that support Rapid Growth and Economic Development, not just Macroeconomic Stabilization
The Need for Public Investment-Led Economic Policies • According to conservative economists, increased Public Investment will: • ‘Crowd out’ (displace) private investment • Cause accelerating inflation and appreciation of the exchange rate • Increase the Fiscal Deficit and the Public Debt • Public Investment Has Been in Long-Term Decline (See graph): From 10% to 7% of GDP
11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 Simple average Weighted average Public Investment in Developing Countries, 1970-2000 (as a share of GDP)
Why Is Increasing Public Investment Justified? • It will stimulate private investment, not dampen it (example: electricity) • It will increase the productive capacity of the economy so that inflation is contained • Governments should borrow to finance public investment (deficit financing) • It creates future revenue and welfare benefits • Current revenue should cover current expenditures • So incurring deficits is normal for investment purposes (ODA finances larger deficits)
The Macroeconomic Implicationsof Expanding Basic Utilities • Fiscal policies need to be more expansionary (investment focused) • Monetary policies should be consistent with fiscal expansion • Low inflation targets (3-5%) can be counter-productive • Achieving such targets can drive up real rates of interest • Such interest rates slow private investment and make public borrowing more expensive: the result is a vicious circle
What Are the Alternative Sources of Financing? • For low-income countries, a dramatic scaling up of Official Development Assistance is needed • Such a scaling up need not endanger macroeconomic stability (e.g., accelerating inflation and causing a ‘Dutch Disease’ appreciation) • Refer to the Conference Papers from the IPC-supported Global Conference on “Gearing Macroeconomic Policies to Reverse the HIV/AIDS Epidemic” www.undp-povertycentre.org/aids.htm • Conclusions: 1) concerns about instability are inflated and 2) if there are such problems, they can be managed.
Investment-Focused ODA • See the New IMF Analytical Framework: • ODA should be ‘SPENT’: the Government should spend more based on ODA financing of a larger deficit • ODA should be ‘ABSORBED’: the Central Bank should sell the ODA-supplied foreign exchange in order to finance imports • Otherwise the purpose of ODA is defeated
Investment-Focused ODA • The recent 2007 Evaluation of PRGF countries in sub-Saharan Africa by IMF’s Independent Evaluation Office found: • Governments spent only 28% of ODA (72% was saved) • So almost three-quarters of ODA was not used for development purposes!!! • Worse still, if the inflation rate exceeded 5% in a country, only 15% of ODA, on average, was spent by governments
Monetary Policies and Inflation • But IMF now recognizes that inflation rates of 5-10% need not be harmful to growth • Maintaining inflation rates of 3-5%, as in the past, can often be unduly restrictive • Empirical evidence suggests that even inflation rates up to 15% are not likely to be harmful • Supply shocks (oil; food) can temporarily drive inflation rates above 10%
Inflation Has Declined in AfricaIt has been 5-10% since 1997
The Impact of ODA • Central Banks ‘Absorbed’ only 63% of ODA (i.e., sold foreign exchange) • 37% of ODA was used to build up International Reserves • There are three possible uses of ODA: • Central Bank Reserves • Private Capital Outflow • Financing of Imports (a transfer of real resources: widening the current account)
Using ODA Effectively • Is it justifiable to use ODA to build up reserves? • Reserves substitute for the transfer of real resources into the country • A modest build-up could be warranted as a means to address Aid Volatility • The Problem: Central Banks ‘sterilize’ the monetary impact of ODA, driving up interest rates in order to contain inflation
A Danger of Exchange-Rate Appreciation?? • The IMF hypothesis: • More government spending domestically (on non-tradables) increases inflation • Inflation appreciates the exchange rate • Appreciation damages the international competitiveness of exports • But in sub-Saharan Africa (as in Asia) aid surges have been associated with Depreciation (See Graph)
ZMB COG 250 CMR SLE EGY MRT CIV NGA Real Overvaluation NER ZWE SDN DZA RWA BFA GAB TZA TCD GMB 200 BDI SEN CAF ZAR KEN TGO BWA MAR LSO TUN MWI GHA GIN MDG 150 ETH UGA ZAF MOZ 50 100 0 10 20 30 40 Foreign Aid %GNI overvalue Fitted values The Size of Aid Is Correlated with Depreciation in Africa
A Danger of Exchange-Rate Appreciation?? • The danger of inflation depends on the supply response to increased demand • Fiscal policies (that increase government spending) and monetary policies (that sell foreign exchange) need to be coordinated (see IPC Working Paper #10 & Conference Papers) • But coordination of policies on whose terms? • Fiscal policies have to be consistent with the restrictive monetary policies of the Central Bank???
Policy Coordination for Scaling Up • Choose the opposite: monetary policies should be supportive of expansionary fiscal policies • Short-term inflation and even some appreciation could be part of the adjustment process • Relative prices need to adjust in order to transfer resources domestically and facilitate their import into the country • The exchange rate can be managed to deal with such short-term problems (along with coordinating fiscal and monetary policies)
The Problem of Aid Volatility • The volatility of aid is the chief problem, not so much domestic macroeconomic instability • ODA needs not only to be scaled up but also made predictable • Otherwise it imparts instability to the budgeting process and contributes to macroeconomic instability