400 likes | 417 Views
ECON 102.004 – Principles of Microeconomics. S&W, Chapter 4 Using Demand and Supply Instructor: Mehmet S. Tosun, Ph.D. Department of Economics University of Nevada, Reno. Lecture Outline. Elasticity Price elasticity of demand and supply Elasticity and demand and supply shifts
E N D
ECON 102.004 – Principles of Microeconomics S&W, Chapter 4 Using Demand and Supply Instructor: Mehmet S. Tosun, Ph.D. Department of Economics University of Nevada, Reno
Lecture Outline • Elasticity • Price elasticity of demand and supply • Elasticity and demand and supply shifts • Government intervention in markets • Shortages and surpluses
Sensitivity to Price Changes • Firms need to know how much demand changes when prices change. • Will an increase in price raise a firm's revenue even though the quantity sold falls? • If a firm raises its price, it loses customers. How many?
Price Elasticity and Revenues • Firms earn revenue from sales; total revenue TR = pQ. • If p rises but Q falls, what happens to TR? Which effect dominates? • If %p > %Q, then TR. • If %p < %Q, then TR.
The Price Elasticity of Demand (a) • e = %Qd/%p = (Qd/Qd)/(p/p). • Elasticity of demand isalways negative since when p increases Qd falls on any demand curve. • e = -4 = %Qd/%p means a 1% increase in price results in a 4% fall in sales • Demand is very elastic. • Consumers are very sensitive to small changes in price. • If the price is $1, a 1% increase in price is 1¢ • In response the quantity demanded falls by 4%, so 1 out of every 25 consumers is sensitive to a 1¢ change in the price.
The Price Elasticity of Demand (b) • Demand is more elastic when many very close substitutes are available.
The Price Elasticity of Demand (c) • Demand curves have different elasticities at different prices. • If e > 1, demand is elastic. • If e = 1, demand is unit elastic. • If e < 1, demand is inelastic. • The cutoff point is an elasticity of 1.
Total Revenue • The relationship between the price elasticity of demand and revenue changes when elasticity equals 1. • When the price rises, if e = 1, then any increase in price will result in an equal decrease in quantity demanded, so TR remains constant. • If e < 1, inelastic demand, then any increase in price will result in a smaller decrease in quantity demanded, so TR rises. • If e > 1, elastic demand, then for any increase in price the result will be a large decrease in quantity demanded, so TR falls.
Examples of Price Elasticity (a) • Necessities, such as basic foods, have an inelastic demand since there are no close substitutes. • The price elasticity for luxury goods is high. • Price elasticity is a local measure. • If e = 4, then a 1% change in price causes a 4% fall in the quantity demaned • But we cannot say that a 20% increase in price causes an 80% decrease in the quantity demanded.
Use of Price Elasticities in Practice: An Example From Cigarette Tax Impact Calculations
Cigarette Tax Impacts • The impact of different cigarette tax increase scenarios for West Virginia • Price elasticity of demand for cigarettes is the key parameter • Cross-border sales and internet sales make demand more elastic than expected
Changing Elasticity Along a Demand Curve • A given demand curve may have a section where demand is elastic, unit elastic and inelastic.
Elasticity of Demand Over Time • Demand curves tend to be more elastic in the long run as consumers have more time to adapt to price changes.
The Price Elasticity of Supply • Supply curves usually slope up, have positive slope. • The elasticity of supply is usually positive. • Supply elasticity = %Qs/%p = (Qs/Qs)/(p/p).
Examples of the Elasticity of Supply • The supply of oil is inelastic; elasticity < 1. So it is relatively difficult to increase the supply of oil. • The supply of chicken is elastic; elasticity > 1. So it is relatively easy to increase the supply of chicken.
Elasticity along the Supply Curve • Different points on the supply curve have different elasticities. • At low output, the elasticity of supply is quite high, while at high output it is quite low.
The Short Run versus the Long Run (a) • When a product can be stored, demand will be much more price sensitive in the short run than in the long run. • Example: cans of tuna are more price sensitive than emergency auto repairs. • When a product or service is part of a system, demand will be much more price sensitive in the long run than in the short run. • Example: the price elasticity for gasoline was low following price jumps in 1970s because it took time to get rid of gas‑guzzling automobiles.
The Short Run versus the Long Run (b) • The shorter the time frame, the less substitution is possible; the longer the time frame, the more substitution is possible. • In the short run, demand is less elastic than in the long run. • In the short run, some inputs are fixed, so supply is difficult to change, while in the long run, all inputs are variable. • As with demand, short‑run elasticities of supply are lower than long‑run elasticities of supply. • Once a farm crop is planted, no more can be produced in that growing cycle, but in the long run, more or less acreage can be allocated to a crop.
Elasticity and Shifts in Demand and Supply (a) • What are the effects of shifts of demand and supply on price and quantity? • Depends on the elasticity of demand and supply.
Elasticity and Shifts in Demand and Supply (b) • In this Figure, the supply curve is nearly horizontal. • If the demand shifts to the right, output increases but the price stays much the same. The shift in demand is reflected mostly in a change of quantity.
Elasticity and Shifts in Demand and Supply (c) • In this figure, the supply curve is close to vertical. • Such a curve might arise from the market for original van Gogh paintings. • If the demand shifts up and to the right, the quantity supplied remains the same but the price increases. • The shifts in demand are reflected mostly in price changes.
Elasticity and Shifts in Demand and Supply (d) • In this figure, demand is fairly flat. • Such a situation might arise with Coke, assuming that Pepsi is a perfect substitute. • In this case, a shift in the supply curve is reflected primarily in a change of quantity. is
Elasticity and Shifts in Demand and Supply (e) • In this figure, we have a vertical demand curve. • This might occur for heart transplants. • In this case, a shift in the supply curve is completely reflected in price.
Long‑Run versus Short‑Run Adjustments • In the long run, supply and demand are both more elastic than in the short run. • So long‑run supply and demand curves are both flatter than their short‑run counterparts • Therefore demand and supply shifts are reflected in prices to a greater extent in the short run than in the long run.
Tax Policy and the Law of Supply and Demand (b) (cont.) • A tax on cheddar cheese would drive consumers to buy other cheeses, causing a sharp drop in quantity with only a small change in price. • Consumers would pay a small part of the tax and cheddar cheese producers would pay most of the tax.
Shortages and Surpluses (a) • When Qd = Qs, economists say that the market clears. • Instances where the market does not clear are shortages or surpluses. • A shortage means that people who are willing to pay the going price cannot find the good. • A surplus means that goods go unsold at the going price.
Shortages and Surpluses (b) • In this figure, the horizontal gap between Qd and Qs is the size of the shortage. Consumers compete to get a bargain.
Shortages and Surpluses (b) (cont.) • In this figure, the horizontal gap between Qd and Qs is the size of the surplus. • Now sellers compete to "move the merchandise." • The rate of adjustment depends on the kind of market as well as the size of the surplus.
Government Involvement • Governments are often asked to interfere with the outcomes of the law of supply and demand because they are politically undesirable to some people. • If rents on apartments are seen as too expensive, there will be pressure on city hall to regulate the market for apartments. • If wages are seen as being too low, there will be pressure on the government to regulate the labor market. • An obvious way to try to circumvent the law of supply and demand is to legislate the price of an object. • Usually, such legislation involves either price ceilings or price floors.
Price Ceilings • Price ceilings are popular government controls on basic goods such as food, shelter, and oil. • An example of a price ceiling is rent control.
Price Ceilings (cont.) • In the long run, the problem is worse. • As this figure shows, long‑run supply is more price elastic, so the effect of a price ceiling on quantity is more pronounced in the long run.
Price Floors • Agricultural subsidies: Farmers participating in the federal commodity programs receive a target (floor) price for their crops. • Price supports given to farmers are one of the most expensive price floors in the U.S. economy.
Price Floors (cont.) • If the market price for farmers' crops fall below this price floor, the U.S. Department of Agriculture pays them the difference. • The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) has estimated the savings which would occur to the federal government if the price floor were reduced 3% a year starting in 1996. • The estimated savings were $501 million in 1996, $1.38 billion in 1997, $2.38 billion in 1998, $3.34 billion in 1999, and over $4.1 billion in 2000. • The CBO also pointed out that many farmers might opt out of the price support framework. • If they did, they would be free to plant as much or as little of a crop as they desired. This new found flexibility would lower their lost revenue.
Alternative Solutions • Attempts to get around the law of supply and demand generally do not work. • If the government wants to solve social problems, it should try another way. • If the government wants higher wages for unskilled labor, it can attempt to increase the demand for such labor. • If it wants affordable housing, it can subsidize housing. • Such methods often generate some problems of their own but are usually more effective than disregarding the law of supply and demand.