1 / 24

Limiting Currency Volatility to Stimulate Goods Market Integration: A Price Based Approach by David Parsley and

Limiting Currency Volatility to Stimulate Goods Market Integration: A Price Based Approach by David Parsley and Shang-Jin Wei Vanderbilt University Brookings Institution. Introduction. Does exchange rate stabilization affect goods market integration?

dillon
Download Presentation

Limiting Currency Volatility to Stimulate Goods Market Integration: A Price Based Approach by David Parsley and

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Limiting Currency Volatility to Stimulate Goods Market Integration: A Price Based Approach by David Parsley and Shang-Jin Wei Vanderbilt University Brookings Institution

  2. Introduction • Does exchange rate stabilization affect goods market integration? • We distinguish two types of stabilization • Instrumental - reducing exchange rate volatility through intervention in the fx market • Institutional - reducing volatility through an explicit currency board or common currency

  3. Introduction • Two strands of empirical research into goods market integration: • studies examining actual flows of goods • price-based studies (e.g., PPP, LOP) • We adopt a price-based approach • a unique multi-country data set on prices of very disaggregated products (e.g., light bulbs & onions)

  4. Studies of observed trade flows • McCallum (95), Wei (96), Heliwell (98) • conclusion: observed volume of trade across national boundaries are much less than within countries • Rose (2000), Frankel and Rose (2000), Rose and Engel (2000), Rose and van Wincoop (2001) • conclusion: common currencies increase bilateral trade by as much as 300%

  5. Limitations of observed trade flows • Two countries may have similar endowments and autarkic prices  low trade • two countries may trade extensively with a 3rd country but little w/each other • Wei (1996) argues welfare implications from observed trade flows need auxiliary assumptions

  6. Intuition • If two countries produce similar (highly substitutable) output, increased trade may raise welfare only marginally • Alternatively, if two countries have distinct comparative advantages, a slight rise in trade may substantially raise welfare

  7. Economist Intelligence UnitPrice Data • Local currency price comparisons for > 160 goods and services from up to 122 cities • We select 95 goods and 83 cities

  8. Sample of Economist Price Data

  9. Cities Included

  10. Our Approach • Let be the U.S. dollar price of good k in city i at time t. For a given city pair (i,j) and a given good k at a time t, we define the common currency percentage price difference as:

  11. Our Approach • We study all bilateral price comparisons the data allow. • There are 3403 city pairs (=(83x82)/2) – each with 11 (annual) time periods. • Thus, for each of the 95 prices the vector of price deviations will contain 37,433 (3403x11) observations without missing values.

  12. Dispersion in Price Differences • We focus on the cross sectional dispersion (across goods) of common currency price differentials for each city-pair and time period • Any particular realization of the common currency price differential, Q(ij,k,t) can be either positive or negative without triggering arbitrage as | Q(ij,k,t) | < the cost of arbitrage

  13. Dispersion and Market Integration • The existence of arbitrage costs implies that must fall within a range • Any reduction to barriers to trade (i.e., movements toward market integration) should reduce the no-arbitrage range. Therefore the strategy we adopt is to study a measure of the dispersion of Q(ij,k,t) through time

  14. Regression analysis • We estimate the following baseline equation:

  15. Discussion • Dispersion increases with distance • Exchange rate variability increases dispersion • reducing it to zero from the sample average, reduces dispersion by .26% (=.067*.039*100) • Participating in a Hard Peg • reduces dispersion by 4.4% - an order of magnitude bigger

  16. Discussion (continued) • Being a member of the CFA has no effect • Being a member of the euro ~ to hard peg • Being in a political union (US) has the largest institutional effect

  17. Tariff Equivalents • Effect of the euro: ~ 4 percentage point reduction in tariffs  on the same order of magnitude as the elimination of tariffs under the common market program • Effect of reducing xr volatility to zero for any random pair of countries is only 0.3% • Effect of political & economic Union (U.S.) ~13 percentage point reduction in tariffs

  18. Summary • Institutional exchange rate stabilization has a much larger effect than instrumental stabilization • reducing xr vol < hard peg < full economic & political integration • The effect is non-trivial. On the order of the common market effect • A non-credible peg (CFA) has no effect

  19. Robustness & Extensions • Additional explanatory variables • re-definitions of explanatory variables • different measures of dependent variable • alternative econometric specifications

  20. Conclusions • Institutional exchange rate stabilization matters for goods market integration. • The economic benefits of currency unions (Hard pegs) are an order of magnitude larger than simply reducing exchange rate vol to zero • Our results suggest that further economic and political integration can have an additional substantial impact on goods market integration

More Related