490 likes | 682 Views
Technology, structural change and growth. Summer 2014. Objectives of the paper. To present basic insights on structural change and growth in a simple framework To show some empirical evidence and stylized facts that are consistent with the “structural change” story.
E N D
Technology, structural change and growth Summer 2014
Objectives of the paper • To present basic insights on structural change and growth in a simple framework • To show some empirical evidence and stylized facts that are consistent with the “structural change” story
Variables and interrelations • Technology gap (TN/TS)= G • Asymmetries in productivity [ (pS/pN) = p] which combined with relative wages (W = WS/WN) • specialization pattern (N) + patterns of domestic and world demand • Income elasticity ratio (e=eS/eN) • relative growth (y = yN/yS=e(N)) • Feed back to the technology gap and wages
Starting point • The starting point: the international diffusion of technology is slow and asymmetric (North-South technology gap) • Technology diffuses only partially to the South and is highly localized in few activities • A Schumpeterian flavor: technical change and innovation as the driving force of development.
Impactson: a) Heterogeneity (implications for employment and income distribution / duality / informality) b) Specialization (implicationsforgrowth, technicalchange and macro stability)
a) Heterogeneity • Large differences in labor productivity emerge within and between sectors • Graphic: two structures that differ in terms of number of sectors, technological intensity (complexity) and asymmetries in labor productivity
How specialization emerges: N is an index of technological complexity
b) Specialization • Ranking sectors according with South-North relative productivity p • Unitary costs depends on the productivity gap and relative wage • The productivity gap is higher in sectors which are more technologically-intensive (comparative advantage of the South is lower in high-tech sectors) • Given the wage ratio, the South specializes in sectors with lower technological intensity
Dynamics of relative productivity • Relative South-North productivity: • p = p S / p N • it increases with relative growth and falls with the technological intensity of the goods: a, b and a are technological parameters
Relative wages • In our examples relative wages will be considered constant, but they can easily be made a function of the diversification of the productive structure or of the relative rate of growth in South and North
c) Growth (Keynesian side) -> The pattern of specialization implies lower dynamism of world and domestic demand for Southern goods -> a less articulated productive structure gives rise to losses of effective demand and a strong propensity to import that reduces the momentum of growth and leads to BOP and exchange rate crisis
Falling behind • Growth will be constrained by external disequilibrium • BOP constraint: yS/yN= e=eX/eM • Elasticity ratio depends on N: e = hN • Falling behind: Low income elasticity of the demand for exports and high income elasticity of the demand for imports, yS< yN
e / A N N 1 From specialization to growth
Macrodynamics • The technology gap shapes relative productivities (box A) • This in combination with relative wages define the pattern of specialization (boxes A and D) • Specialization defines the BOP-constrained rate of relative growth (B) • Growth defines labor demand and the absorption of informality and subsistence workers (E)
Shocks and policies • Industrial and technological policy • Vent for surplus versus Dutch disease • Unilateral trade liberalization
Technological policy • An active technological policy reduces the technology gap enhancing diversification towards sectors with higher technological-intensity and higher demand growth
Structural change and specialization AMÉRICA LATINA Y ASIA: PATRÓN DE CAMBIO ESTRUCTURAL Y PARTICIPACIÓN EN LAS EXPORTACIONES, 1985-2011 Fuente: Comisión Económica para América Latina y el Caribe (CEPAL), sobre la base de UnitedNationsCommodityTradeStatisticsDatabase (COMTRADE).
Productivitygrowth in LA and SE Asia LatinAmerica (12 countries) and Asia (7 countries): labor productivity (1980 = 100) Fuente: Comisión Económica para América Latina y el Caribe (CEPAL), sobre la base de cifras oficiales de los países de la región, de la base de datos Laborsta de la Organización Internacional del Trabajo (OIT), y de WorldDevelopmentIndicators (WDI) del Banco Mundial.
An economy that fails to diversify will not be able to raise employment and productivity at the same time Latin America (12 countries): labor productivity and value added, 1980-2010 a (thousands and millions of 2000 US dollars)
Case 2: Dutch disease • A positive shock in commodity prices leads initially to higher growth, more learning and investment (vet for surplus) • If the real exchange rate rises, then there will be less diversification and slower growth at the end of the adjustment (regressive structural change) • A key point is the policy reaction to the shock and how to neutralize appreciation
Case 3: unilateral trade liberalization • Reduces diversification • Increases heterogeneity • Rising productivity levels in commodities, falling in industry • Of course trade liberalization plus industrial policy may significantly change the outcomes
Brief notes on evolutionary microdynamics • Why technical change does not diffuse uniformly across countries and within sectors? • Which policies close the technology gap and which policies lead to divergence? • Conventional micro usually avoids these questions; on the other hand, they are at the core of evolutionary micro
Evolutionary perspective on technical change 1 • It has a critical tacit component that could not be obtained from importing capital goods nor from reading manual and other forms of codified information; • Cumulativeness: firms that are closer to the technological frontier have an advantage in innovation and will tend to increase their distance with respect to the laggards (cumulative processes leading to virtuous or vicious cycles)
Evolutionary perspective on technical change 2 • It is subject to path-dependency, i.e. the evolution of capabilities depends on previous experience and directions of past learning • There exists complementary between sectors and capabilities, in such a way that externalities and increasing returns are crucial at both the industrial and economy levels • There is irreversibility in the building of certain (physical and technological) assets, which cannot be just abandoned or replaced
Convergence and divergence • There is no reason for naïve optimism about convergence. Path-dependency and cumulativeness lead to strong inertia in the patterns of learning and specialization. • On the other hand, catching up may be possible under specific circumstances, when industrial policies and institution-building create a favorable environment for learning from imported technology.
Industrial and technological policy • Market forces tend to endogenously reinforce asymmetries; active policies are required to enhance diffusion • Focus on institutions, complementarities and increasing returns rather than on flexibility in the goods, financial and labor markets.
The other supply side • For having this virtuous cycle there must be in place an articulated institutional framework in which firms and non-profit organisations (particularly those directly related to education and R&D) are nested in a network of technological and productive flows which enhances the problem-solving capabilities of producers and stimulates the various forms of interactive learning – what has been called the National System of Innovation, NSI (Nelson, Freeman, Lundvall, Metcalf).