1 / 55

Economic Integration and Regional Industrial Specialization Patterns: New Evidence from the Canadian-US FTA Experience

Economic Integration and Regional Industrial Specialization Patterns: New Evidence from the Canadian-US FTA Experience. Michel BEINE (Unversity of Lille, France & University of Brussels, Belgium): mbeine@ulb.ac.be Serge Coulombe (University of Ottawa, Canada): scoulomb@uottawa.ca

dot
Download Presentation

Economic Integration and Regional Industrial Specialization Patterns: New Evidence from the Canadian-US FTA Experience

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Economic Integration and Regional Industrial Specialization Patterns: New Evidence from the Canadian-US FTA Experience Michel BEINE (Unversity of Lille, France & University of Brussels, Belgium): mbeine@ulb.ac.be Serge Coulombe (University of Ottawa, Canada): scoulomb@uottawa.ca Workshop in International Economics, KU Leuven, October 13 2004

  2. The Issues • Impact of trade integration between Canada and the US • Impact on the regional production structures • Impact in terms of absolute specialisation • Impact in tems of relative specialisation • Impact in terms of share of intra-industry trade

  3. Why is the Canadian-US case interesting? • The FTA (1989) is one of the most spectacular integration process: trade share in GDP increased from 0.51 to 0.86 between 1990 and 2000 (Coulombe, 2003) (not a Customs Union) • This increase is not evenly spead-out across the 10 provinces (Beine & Coulombe, 2003) • The ratio international trade/interprovincial trade strongly increases for Quebec and Ontario, less for the other ones • Despite the strong effects, the FTA raised concerns • Short run costs (Job losses, Worker’s displacement) (Trefler, 2004, forthcoming AER) • Will Canada become a peripheral region of the US, specialized in primary products ?

  4. Why is the Canadian-US case interesting? • The Canadian case allows to shed some new light on the general issue of the relationship between trade integration and specialisation • Two opposite views: • Krugman, 1991: trade integration leads to specialisation • Frankel and Rose, 1998: trade integration favours diversification of production structures • This has strong implications for economic policy: increases in risk exposure (absolute specialization); future of the intra-provincial redistribution system (relative specialization) • Our paper brings 4 contributions to the empirical literature

  5. Contributions of this paper • Captures trade integration in a more precise way : use of (provincial) trade weighted tariffs between Canada and the US as a measure of trade integration rather than • Time dummies for FTA (Acharya et al.,2001); • Time (European studies : Amiti (1998, 1999 for instance) • Trade flows (endogeneity problem) • Conduct the analysis at the regional level. Important because • The Core-periphery structure • The heterogeneity of the trade integration process across provinces

  6. Contributions of this paper • Combine the pure time series information (1980-1998) with the cross-section information (10 provinces) • Panel data with more observations  more robust econometric relationships • Allows to disentangle short-run and long-run effects (Trefler, 2002) • Clear distinction between absolute and relative specialisation: • absolute specialisation important for assessing the exposure to specific economic shocks • relative specialisation important for the assessing the viability of inter-provincial redistribution schemes

  7. Theoretical background • Initial contributions from the new economic geography approach (Krugman, 1991 ; Krugman and Venables, 1995) see trade integration (decrease of transport costs) as a strong agglomerating force • Nevertheless, no clear prediction of the impact of trade integration in terms of specialisation because: • Recent contributions predict U relationship (new dispersion of activities for very low trade costs) • Specialisation and concentration are different concepts • Relocation of a given industry followed by agglomeration of other industries (backward/forward linkages)  need to disentangle short-run and long-run effects of trade integration

  8. The empirical literature • Preliminary studies of Krugman (1993) and De Grauwe and Van Haverbeke (1993) based on the comparison between countries and regions  positive link between integration and specialisation • Studies of the European integration process: mixed evidence • Increase in absolute specialisation (Amiti, 1998 & 1999) vs no trend (Sapir, 1996) • Midelfart et al. (2000) find increase in relative specialisation after 1980 while Hallet (2000) finds a steady decrease between 1980 and 1995 • Results sample-specific; level of disagregation matters !!! • Studies of the Canadian-US FTA • Sawchuk and Sydor (2001) : moderate diversification of Canadian manufacturing exports • Head and Ries (2001): stability over time of absolute specialisation

  9. The Data • Use of import and export data at the SIC 4 level (290 industries) between Canadian provinces and US • Covers the pre-FTA and the FTA period : 1980-1998 important because trade flows strongly increase before 1989. • Building of indexes of • absolute specialisation : Herfindahl indexes • relative specialisation : K-spec indexes • share of intra-industry trade : Grubbel and Lloyd indexes

  10. Specialisation indexes • Absolute specialisation: Herfindahl indexes: • Based on the sum of the squared of the shares over all industries • Number comprised between 1/290 between 1 • The lower, the more diversified

  11. Specialisation indexes • Relative specialisation: K-spec indexes indexes: • Captures the gap between province i and the average of the 9 other provinces • K-spec=0 if industrial structure identical from rest of Canada • K-spec=1 if industrial structure completely different from rest of Canada

  12. Trade integration • Provincial trade weighted tariffs (TWT) : • Reduction began well before the implementation of the FTA (1989)  need to consider the pre-FTA period • Striking heterogeneity of the trade integration process across provinces: see NF vs SK  need to conduct the analysis at the regional level • The FTA is a clean experiment :no strategic reduction in tariffs • Endogeneity of the TWT because possible endogeneity of the industry weights  alternative approach with constant weights:

  13. Control variables • CAD-USD Exchange rate volatility (realized volatility as suggested by Andersen et al. 2001) • CAD-USD Exchange rate misalignements :Acharya et al., 2001 argue that the increase in trade flows was mainly due to depreciation of the CAD and not to the FTA (however captured by a dummy variable) • Canadian Business Cycle (extracted from Beine and Coulombe, 2003) • US Business Cycle • Canadian Provincial Business Cycle (extracted from Beine and Coulombe, 2003)

  14. The benchmark econometric model • Dynamic Panel Data Model: • Disentangles short-run(f3) from long-run effects (- f2/ f1) • 3 different estimation methods : • Pooled Least Squares with fixed effects and White heteroskedasticity consistent standard errors • Feasible Generalized Least Squares with cross-sectional weighted regressions to account for cross-sectional heteroskedasticity • Seemingly Unrelated Regressions (to take with caution) • Extending the benchmark specification with interaction terms in order to refine the interpretation

  15. Two potential problems • Estimation bias with dynamic panel data for T small and N large (Nickell, 1981; Kiviet, 1995) • Here T=18 and N=10  if any, bias should be limited • IV generates more problems than it solves (poor efficiency) • Adjustement speed is high  if any, bias should also be limited • Ignoring parameter heterogeneity might generate substantial bias (Pesaran and Smith, 1995)  • Heterogeneous specifications and Mean group estimates • Results similar than those obtained with the benchmark specification

  16. Successive investigations • Impacts of TWT on absolute and relative diversification • Distinction between the all sectors case (290) and manufacturing sectors (213) (Trefler, 2004)  primary products are important, especially for some provinces (AB, SK, NF) • Distinction between trade with the US and with the ROW • Interaction specifications • Heterogeneous specifications • Robustness analysis : serial correlation, constant weights in TWT • Impact of TWT on ITT

  17. Results for absolute specialization • In the long run, the reduction of TWT (trade integration) induces more diversification • Very robust result to different methods, to heterogeneous specifications, estimations in logs for elasticities (this paper, short version) • Result holds for the all sector case and the manufacturing sectors • Estimates of the speed of adjustment suggests that: • Mean half life equal to about 2.3 years for all sectors • Mean half life equal to about 2 years for the manufacturing sectors • Short run effect of trade integration : more specialisation (result less significant and less robust however)

  18. Results for absolute specialization • Consistent with a story of • initial concentration in one or a few provinces of a given industry • agglomeration of different industries • The industrial production patterns are driven by the Canadian-US FTA: • no impact of index computed from exports to ROW • no long short-run and long-run impacts of TWT on specialisation indexes computed from exports to ROW • No strong effect of the share of ITT on absolute specialisation : if any, more ITT leads to more diversification

  19. Results fromheterogeneous specifications • Long-run impact is stronger for Alberta, New Founland, Quebec, Manitoba, Nova Scottia • Long run impact less obvious for Ontario • Mean Group estimates of Long-run impact (Pesaran and Smith, 1999) consistent with previous estimates • Heterogeneity also with respect to the short run effect • Mean Group estimates of short-run impact also in line with previous estimates

  20. Results for relative specialization • TWT do not exert any direct significant impact  trade integration does not lead to more different provinces • On the contrary, indirect effect of trade integration: trade integration increase absolute diversification which in turn is found to make provinces more similar • No interaction from relative to absolute diversification

  21. Results for intra industry trade (IIT) • Mixed evidence on the impact of trade integration • In general, negative impact : trade integration raises the share of IIT: consistent with previous findings (Torstensson , 1996 ) for Sweden • no significant impact for the all sectors case • significant impact for manufacturing sectors • Impact of misalignment of CAD on the share of IIT • Deviations from equilibium exchange rate lead to more IIT • Effect observed for the all sectors case but not for manufacturing  effect goes through primary products • Indeed, heterogeneous specification wrt misalignment show that the impact is driven mainly by the western provinces : AB, BC, SK

  22. Accounting for non stationarity • Important issues: presence of stochastic trends in TWT and Herfindahl indexes • The presence of unit roots in these variables call for specific econometric procedures because: • Inference problems in homogeneous panels (Pedroni, 2003) • Spurious regressions in heterogeneous panels • Long run relationships have to be tested by cointegration tests • The statistical procedures have to integrate the panel dimension: • Panel unit root tests (Levin and Lin, 1993; Pedroni, 2003) • Panel Cointegration tests (pedroni, 1999)

  23. Accounting for non stationarity • Procedures involving • the raw data • the logistic transformation (the interest variables are bounded) • Two different cases: • homogeneous case: the autogressive dynamics is the same in the URT and the cointegration relationship is the same • heterogeneous case: specific autoregressive part and different long-run relationships • Three lag structures in URT : 0 , 1 and 2

  24. Statistical procedures • For unit root tests: • 3 different test statistics • Strong evidence of unit roots for TWT • Mixed evidence of unit roots for Herfindahl (especially in homogeneous case) • Cointegration Tests: • 7 different test statistics • In general, evidence in favour of a long-run relationship • More evidence in the homogeneous case • Lead to the estimate of a an Error correction specification:

  25. Results • The presence of a long-run relationship confirmed: • Positive cointegrating relationship confirmed • Values of the long-run relationship very similar : 2.66 vs [1.15; 3.85] for the all sectors case and 2.80 vs [1.49; 4,14] • In general, heterogeneous specification fully confirmed • Estimates of the adjustement speed in the ECM consistent with previous findings: • Adjustment to equilibrium takes about 4 years for the all sectors case and 3 years for manufacturing sectors (homogeneous case) • Adjustment speed slightly higher for heterogeneous specification • To sum-up: main results robust to the issue of non stationarity

  26. Further robustness analysis • Robustness analysis on the effects of TWT on absolute diversification in different directions • Estimations in logs to obtain short-run and long run elasticities: short run effects not so robust ; long run elasticities very robust (about 20) • Influence of the core-periphery structure captured by the ratio of the primary to manufacturing products : • Results wrt to TWT fully robust • Caution because of endogeneity of the ratio • Issue of the endogeneity of the weights in the TWT: • Tackled with a measure of TWT fixing the weights to the time average over the 1980-2001 period • Results similar wrt long-run effects and adjsument speed, less wrt to short-run effects

  27. Further robustness analysis (continued) • Recursive regressions, dropping one province at a time: • Long-run stimates very stable • Results are not driven by a particular provincial dynamics • Wiping out potential time trends : time dummies to capture general decrease of the tariffs  results robust : the cross-sectional variance matters !!!! • Serial correlation (Dan Trefler ’s comment) : important in dynamic models : no evidence of serial correlation  results robust

  28. Conclusion and extensions • Main result : Canadian-US trade integration has led to : • long-run diversification of Canadian provincial production structures • short-run specialisation (less robust) • Trade integration does not make Canadian provinces more different from each others • Economic implications: • No increased exposure to specific shocks • No strenghtening of the core-periphery structure • No additional pressure on the inter-provincial redistribution schemes or on market adjustement mechanisms (migration, …)

  29. Conclusion and extensions • Other economic implications: provinces are not equally affected by exchange rate developments: sensitivity to misalignement is very different across the Canadian provinces  consistent with the main conclusion of Beine and Coulombe (2003) • Application to EU enlargement : choice of the integration measure ? • Role of the disaggregation level : is diversification a vertical or an horizontal phenomenon ? (on going) • Comments welcome - thanks

More Related