530 likes | 869 Views
Chapter 13: The Hospital Services Industry Health Economics. Outline. Hospital Industry Structure Hospital Conduct Industry Performance. Hospital Industry Structure. Is the hospital market competitive? In general, competitiveness depends on: number of hospitals barriers to entry
E N D
Outline • Hospital Industry Structure • Hospital Conduct • Industry Performance
Hospital Industry Structure • Is the hospital market competitive? • In general, competitiveness depends on: • number of hospitals • barriers to entry • demand/ number of buyers • types of services/technology • asymmetric information (patients & hospitals)
Hospital Industry Structure • # of hospitals declined 15%. • # of beds declined 27%. • Community hospitals • medical and surgical services. • Short-term stays (30 days). • Nonprofit 61% • For-profit 15% • State & Local 24%
The Relevant Market for Hospital Services • Does existence of a large number of hospitals increase competitive market conditions for any given patient? • What is the relevant product market? • What is the relevant geographic market?
The Relevant Product Market • By Diagnosis • All hospitals treating heart attack patients or providing hernia repair. • Levels of care • Primary care - prevention, early detection, treatment. • Secondary care - more sophisticated treatment • Tertiary care - arrests disease in progress. • Quaternary care - med school affiliation. • Research orientation.
The Relevant Product Market • Market for primary/secondary care local; tertiary care may be regional/national in scope. • Competitors are not just hospitals. • Physician clinics, outpatient surgery centers can provide similar services.
The Relevant Geographic Market • Those hospitals offering similar cluster of inpatient services within same geographic area. • Define such that small % of people leave to purchase hospital services elsewhere, & small % of people enter from outside the area to buy services. • Mobile and Huntsville, AL are separate geographic markets; Homewood and Vestavia are not.
A Formal Competitiveness Measure • Herfindahl-Hirschman Index i = 1,…N hospitals in a given market. Si = market share (%) of hospital i.
A Formal Competitiveness Measure • Example: 5 hospitals in a market with shares: 35, 30, 20, 10, 5. 352 + 302 + 202 + 102 + 52 = 2650
Properties 1) 0 HHI 10,000 2) Smaller # of hospitals leads to increased HHI which results in a less competitive market. Example: Suppose 2 smallest hospitals merge. 352 + 302 + 202 + 152 = 2750
3) Equal market share for all hospitals leads to lower HHI which results in more competitive market. Example: Suppose 4 hospitals had equal market share. 252 + 252 + 252 + 252 = 2500
Department of Justice challenges a merger when: • Postmerger HHI > 1800, and premerger HHI would increase > 50 points. OR • Postmerger HHI > 1000, and premerger HHI would increase > 100 points. • Postmerger HHI < 1000 seldom challenged by Department of Justice.
Barriers to Entry • Def’n: a condition that imposes higher long-run costs of production on a new entrant than those born by firms in the market already. • Institutional Barriers: Certificate of Need (CON) laws. • Required in certain states to open a hospital (designed to limit excess capacity).
Barriers to Entry • Economic Barriers a) Economies of scale - empirical evidence. • Long run average costs of a community hospital probably reach a minimum at 250 beds. • But estimates indicate cost curve very shallow; i.e., few economies of scale.
b) Learning by doing hypothesis • Over time, higher cumulative output, more experience leads to lower costs, higher quality. • Stone et al. (1992): Relative risk of death for AIDS patients 2 times higher in “low experience” hospitals. • AIDS discharges/10,000 disch. per year top 20% = 43-229 AIDS/10,000 disch. per year in 1988.
Barriers to Entry • Low-experience hospitals also more likely to put patients in ICU, longer stays lead to higher costs. c) multi-hospital systems may achieve more economies of scale, but no empirical evidence.
Even so, will hospital chains dominate the future market? • For-profit chains now focussing on acquiring nonprofits. • Columbia/HCA’s mistake: • acquired or joint ventured w/ weaker hospitals whose cash flow could be improved. • Takeovers would tightly squeeze margins through layoffs, stringent cost controls.
Can acquisition of nonprofits still work? • Advantages for for-profits. 1) NPs have built-in community trust. 2) Affiliated w/ region’s top specialists. 3) Many nonprofits are well-run. • Returns of 15% on net revenue are common. • Consolidation and improved economies of scale could be even more lucrative.
Can acquisition of nonprofits still work? • Advantages to community/hospital: 1) Proceeds of sale go to charitable foundations for indigent care. 2) New FP pays state and federal taxes. 3) Hospital gets access to capital markets which it needs to expand, vertically integrate.
Can acquisition of nonprofits still work? • For-profit managers must be sensitive to community concerns. • “Columbia agreed to operate 24-hour emergency rooms for at least three years at the Boston-area hospitals, provide charity care and be accountable to the state for its community benefits.”
Can acquisition of nonprofits still work? • Nonprofit managers must decide whether to solicit competitive bids. • “I think the bidding process helped get a better price,” says a hospital chairman. • “I’m getting calls telling me ‘don’t you dare pick Columbia,’ while pro-choice advocates object to affiliation with Catholic,” says a hospital board member.
Buyer Characteristics • Major purchasers can exert buying power to obtain price discounts.
How managed care plans exercise buying power. Source: Elizabeth W. Hoy, Richard E. Curtis, and Thomas Rice, “Change and Growth in Managed Care,” Health Affairs 10 (Winter 1991), Exhibit 6.
Even if hospitals reimbursed according to charges, HMOs & PPOs obtain discounts. • More risk placed on hospitals through DRG payment and capitation. • Keep in mind differences between HMOs & PPOs, & within types of HMOs narrowing overtime.
Vertically Integrated Systems • Vertical associations between firms operating in different, but related product markets. • Insurers & hospitals (Allina). • Insurers & physicians (Kaiser). • Physicians & hospitals (PHO). • # of physician practices owned or managed by hospital-based systems rose 60% b/w 1994-1995. • 7,015 to 11,234.
Advantages of Vertical Integration • Solves the agency problem • Aligns incentives of insurers w/ providers, or hospitals w/ physicians. • Solves the monopoly pricing problem. • An integrated hospital will “sell” its inputs to its insurer at marginal costs. • Lowers transactions costs. • Costs of negotiating, writing, monitoring, and enforcing contracts.
Advantages of Vertical Integration • Ensures supply of an input. • Managed-care plans must ensure the supply of services from specialized physicians or hospital facilities. • Improved coordination between firms. • Information systems, review protocols. • Improved monitoring.
Anticompetitive Concerns • Vertical integration could lead to market foreclosure and thus harm market competition. • If there are multiple insurers in a market but only 1 hospital, an exclusive contract b/w 1 insurer and the hospital is potentially anticompetitive. • “Vertical merger does not create or increase the firm’s power to restrict output. The ability to restrict output depends on the share of the market occupied by the firm. Horizontal mergers increase market share, but vertical mergers do not.” (Robert Bork, 1978)
Structure: Putting it all Together Is the hospital market competitive, or not? Case Study: UNITED STATES OF AMERICA, Plaintiff, vs. MERCY HEALTH SERVICES and FINLEY TRI-STATES HEALTH GROUP, INC. Defendants.
Filed October 17, 1995 • Mercy and Finley: only 2 acute care hospitals in Dubuque, Iowa propose to merge. • Justice Department sues for preliminary injunction.
Facts Dubuque population = 86,403 Mercy: 320 staffed beds, average daily census = 127. Finley: 124 staffed beds, average daily census = 63.
competition - outside 70m radius, but within 100 m. Madison, Wisconsin Waterloo Cedar Rapids Dubuque Freeport, Illinois Iowa City, Iowa
Insurance coverage for Mercy/Finley patients • 50% Medicare/Medicaid • 25% Fee-for-service (traditional indemnity) • 25% Managed care (HMOs, PPOs) • Negotiated 15-30% hospital price discounts.
Justice Department case 1) Where do Dubuque patients go for hospital care? 88% inside (Mercy or Finley) 12% outside 2) Where are Mercy/Finley patients from? 76% inside (Dubuque) 24% outside • Dubuque the relevant geographic market, and merger constitutes a monopoly.
Ruling • District court judge rejects Justice Department’s definition of geographic market as too narrow. • “The government continues to fail to look at the merger within the context of current market trends. All evidence is that there is a great deal of competition for health care dollars…”
“…if DRHS [merged entity] reacted in a noncompetitive manner, an HMO that could successfully induce Dubuque area residents to use alternative hospitals would be at a significant cost advantage.” • “There is also evidence that managed care entities can successfully induce Dubuque residents to use other regional hospitals for their inpatient needs.” Merger of Mercy and Finley would not/could not result in higher prices.
Case Study Conclusion • Even if only one hospital exists in a given geographic region, it may not be able to act as a monopolist • Ability of large, managed care buyers to shift patients can keep the market competitive.
Hospital Conduct • Large #s of sellers and low barriers to entry promote competition. • We expect increased competition to lead to: • Higher output and quality. • Lower price.
However, the hospital market has important differences. • Hospitals don’t necessarily maximize profits. • Government is a major payer • Prices not set competitively. • Consumer less likely to shop around. • Insurance and asymmetric info. • Hospitals compete on the basis of quality (which increases costs) instead of price.
Empirical Evidence • Studies prior to 1983 support the idea of a “Medical Arms Race.” • Regions with more competition have: • More excess bed capacity. • Larger # of duplicate specialized services • 1983: Medicare moved from cost-based reimbursement to prospective payment. • Hospitals reimbursed a predetermined fixed rate for each payment; instead of actual costs
After 1983, increased competition led to: • No impact on hospital costs in 1984-85, even though it increased costs in 1980-83. • Lower Blue Cross PPO-negotiated price for hospital services. • GE slow to introduce positron emission tomography (PET), because insurers less willing to pay for it.
Does Ownership Type Affect Conduct? • Empirical Evidence • Prices higher for for-profit hospitals, but NFP & public hospitals enjoy tax advantages, municipal bond discounts. • Only small differences in costs by ownership type.
Has managed care changed conduct? • Empirical Evidence • HMO hospitalization rates 15-20% lower than those of fee-for-service insurance plans. • However, HMO growth has not led to decrease in total hospital costs per capita at market level.
Maybe further HMO penetration required. • Government still a dominant payer, and reimburses generously. • Maybe managed care doesn’t work. • Outcomes for patients covered by HMOs similar & sometimes better than those for fee-for-service patients.
Hospital Market Performance How have price and quantity changed?
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, CPI Detailed Report (various issues).
Hospital room inflation rate exceeds general rate for all but 1 year. • Despite move to prospective reimbursement by Medicare in 1983, hospital inflation continued. • Possible explanations 1) generous insurance 2) fee-for-service medicine 3) lack of profit motive 4) quality competition
What about Quantity? • . Admission rates, occupancy, average length of stay all declined. • 2. But staffing, outpatient visits rose. Source: American Hospital Association, Hospital Statistics