250 likes | 391 Views
Chapter 13. Malnutrition and Rural Labor markets. In chapter 8 we introduced the capacity curve. It shows the relationship between income (and presumably nutrition) and one’s capacity to work. The capacity curve.
E N D
Chapter 13. Malnutrition and Rural Labor markets In chapter 8 we introduced the capacity curve. It shows the relationship between income (and presumably nutrition) and one’s capacity to work.
The capacity curve Huge gains in work capacity occur initially as income rises but, beyond point A, increase at a decreasing rate. work capacity A income
Imagine that you are paid a piece rate for the work you do. The more work you perform the higher your income. How much higher is given by the slope of the line,v. Therefore the slope of this line corresponds to the piece rate. (The flatter the line, the higher the piece rate) v2 v3 v1 work capacity A income
Kinks in labor supply Note that as the piece rate falls your ability to supply labor falls sharply. Below a piece rate of v3 it becomes impossible to work.
As a result, the labor supply curve resembles the following. This kink corresponds to the tangency of v to the capacity curve piece rate v3 Below v3 the effort I can supply falls sharply quantity of labor supplied
Superimpose a normally shaped labor demand curve on this and note the following For high levels of labor demand the labor market functions normally LS piece rate LD quantity of labor supplied
Superimpose a normally shaped labor demand curve on this and note the following For low levels of labor demand there exists an equilibrium in this market with involuntary unemployment! LS piece rate LD quantity of labor supplied
There is involuntary unemployment in the sense that the distance AB represents a quantity of labor workers would willingly supply at v3. Note that a reduction in wages is not possible! If the piece rate falls below v3 there will be excess demand in rural labor markets forcing wages back up to v3. LS piece rate V3 LD A B quantity of labor supplied
As D. Ray points out ... “We see, then, that the vicious circle is complete in this little model. Lack of labor market opportunities makes for low wages, but it is not only that wages determine work capacity: a low work capacity feeds back on the situation by lowering access to labor markets.” (Ray, p. 493)
Inequality and labor market equilibrium. Property of one’s own (by providing another source of income) raises work capacity. As a small landholder, my wife and children work our land while I go out and work for a large landowner. work capacity A income
Inequality and labor market equilibrium. v3 At v3 I can work far more and earn more than my neighbor who owns no land. All he has to survive on is what he makes. What I make is over and above what my family produces with our little parcel of land. I arrive to work fed. He arrives hungry. work capacity A income
Inequality and labor market equilibrium. v3 v4<v3 At v4 I still have the capacity to work but just barely. work capacity C A income
The minimum wage that one can work for depends on one’s wealth. The preceding implies that for the landless the minimum scale of pay they can work for effectively is v3 minimum piece rate v3 i individuals
The minimum wage that one can work for depends on one’s wealth. Therefore i represents the total number of landless workers. The remaining people within this labor market are arranged in ascending order of their landholdings. minimum piece rate v3 i individuals
The minimum wage that one is willing to work for also depends on one’s wealth. The more land I hold the more I can produce and hence the more I must be offered to work. minimum piece rate v3 i individuals
The solid line represents a combination of the willingness and ability to work curves minimum piece rate v3 i individuals
Up to point Z ability to work is the effective constraint on the labor market. To the right of point Z willingness to work is the effective constraint. minimum piece rate v3 Z i individuals
At a wage rate of v* the quantity of labor supplied would be AB. Individuals to the left of A cannot work as much as they might like to at that wage. Individuals to the right of point Z certainly can work but choose not to. minimum piece rate v* Z A B individuals
At a wage rate of v** the quantity of labor supplied would be CD. CD. Individuals to the left of C cannot work as much as they might like to at that wage. Individuals to the right of point D certainly can work but choose not to. minimum piece rate v** Z C D individuals
The effect of land reform on labor market conditions. At v* the landless peasant is effectively locked out of the labor market. He is like the clumsy little kid during recess when teams are chosen that nobody wants on their team. Meanwhile, whether he wants to or not, the rich landholder could certainly work at a rate of v* v* work capacity A income
Taking land away from the rich landholder and giving some to the landless peasant does the following: It increases the formerly landless peasant’s work capacity. Before he was willing to work at this wage but was simply unable to do so. This leads to an increase in the effective quantity of labor supplied at v*. v* work capacity A income
As far as the rich landholder is concerned ... indiff curve 1 This should increase his willingness to work. prod fn 1 QA indiff curve 2 prod fn 2 Labor effort
The shift encourages more effort But since he is on a lower indifference curve he will not be happy about the changes taking place.
Given the demand for labor we should see the following: piece rate S(pre-reform) LD quantity of labor supplied and demanded
Given the demand for labor we should see the following: As employment increases, production and hence real income increases. piece rate S(pre-reform) S(post-reform) LD quantity of labor supplied and demanded