520 likes | 980 Views
Chapter 5. Beyond Comparative Advantage. Chapter Objectives. Explain why many countries import the same goods they export Analyze the development of regional clusters of production of many exported goods and services Examine some preliminary arguments for trade activism. Introduction.
E N D
Chapter 5 Beyond Comparative Advantage
Chapter Objectives • Explain why many countries import the same goods they export • Analyze the development of regional clusters of production of many exported goods and services • Examine some preliminary arguments for trade activism.
Introduction • Problems with models of trade based exclusively on comparative advantage: • Perform relatively poorly in empirical application; • In particular, they don’t provide a completely compelling account of intra-industry trade. • Besides, countries often seek to alter their comparative advantages through industrial policies • While competitive models provide useful warnings about such policies; • Restricting ourselves to such models makes it difficult to enter certain kinds of policy discussion.
Intra-Industry Trade • Inter-Industry trade– international trade of products between two different industries (steel-for-bread) • Intra-Industry trade– international trade of products made within the same industry (steel-for-steel, bread-for-bread)
Measuring Intra-Industry Trade:The Grubel-Lloyd Index • Grubel-Lloyd (GL) index– Divide IITj by total trade in j (TTj = Xj + Mj) to get: • Xj = Mj→ GLj= 1, all trade is IIT; • Xjor Mj = 0 → GLj= 0, all trade is inter-industry.
Problems in Evaluating IIT • Categorical Aggregation • IIT is a statistical phenomenon, reflecting the fact that trade data are collected at some level of aggregation, but • We are interested in its implications for the theory of international trade. • Thus, we implicitly assume that these are technologically identical goods, but • It is entirely possible that some component of measured IIT is just trade in different goods that fall in the same category. • Trade Imbalance
Magnitude of IIT • IIT is a growing share of total trade • Across sectors, for the US IIT is greatest in industries that we would think of as comparative advantage industries.
Magnitude of IIT (continued) • IIT is a growing share of total trade • Across sectors, for the US IIT is greatest in industries that we would think of as comparative advantage industries. • IIT is most prevalent in trade between industrial countries, but • N-S IIT is not insignificant (though not clear how to interpret N-S IIT).
Explaining Intra-Industry Trade, 1: Perfectly Competitive Markets • No Puzzle: Pure Categorical Aggregation • As an empirical matter, IIT does fall with disaggregation. • HOS Intra-Industry Trade • Technology differences • m < n (“flats”→ specialization), similar factor-intensities • Many countries
Explaining Intra-Industry Trade, 2: Oligopoly & Reciprocal Dumping, A • Suppose that there is a national monopolist in each of two countries. • Suppose that the firms produce an identical product (say, automobiles). • Suppose that the opportunity to trade involves paying a transportation cost to reach the other market. • The opportunity to trade will lead each national monopolist to enter the other’s market. • Since each monopolist is pricing above marginal cost, each observes profit opportunity in the other market.
Explaining Intra-Industry Trade, 2: Oligopoly & Reciprocal Dumping, B • As long as the oligopoly price, taking transportation cost into account yields a profit, both firms will enter the other’s market. • The transportation cost will mean the foreign firm in each market will have a lower market share; but • There will be intra-industry trade in identical products. • Due to transportation costs, trade is strictly wasteful; but • Since the competition lowers prices to consumers, there are gains from trade.
Explaining Intra-Industry Trade, 3: The Linder Hypothesis • Staffan Burenstam Linder (1961) developed a preference based account of intra-industry trade: • Certain goods in every country are produced according to local tastes; • Similarity in per capita income yields similarity in taste (at least for non-standard goods); • As a result, trade in these national varieties will occur, and that trade will be greatest between countries at similar levels of development • Empirical work based on the gravity equation seems consistent with this account
Explaining Intra-Industry Trade: 4, The Gravity Equation, A • This econometric model explains the bilateral trade between countries in terms of their GNPs (Γ) and the distance between them (D): • Why “gravity”? • Newton’s law of gravitation: the attraction between two heavenly bodies is proportional to the product of their masses (i.e. GNPs) and inversely related to their distances.
Explaining Intra-Industry Trade: 4, The Gravity Equation, B • The gravity equation is usually estimated in log-linear form as: • This is usually extended by including: • Cultural distance (e.g. common language); • Historical factors, e.g. common empire; • Political factors, e.g. common currency or customs area • Geographical factors like common border.
Explaining Intra-Industry Trade: 4, The Gravity Equation, C • Characteristic Results: • Two countries with large GNPs trade a lot (as predicted by Linder); • Distance is important; • Borders are important (i.e. there is a Home Market Bias); • At a more disaggregated level, there is some evidence that intra-industry trade is greater in differentiated, rather than standard, products.
Explaining Intra-Industry Trade, 5: Monopolistic Competition, A • A somewhat more formal version of Linder’s approach is based on monopolistic competition • Products are differentiated in some way; • Consumers have a preference for variety; and • There are internal economies of scale in producing any given variety. • The increasing returns to scale in production of varieties means that a single firm, in a single location, will produce each variety.
Explaining Intra-Industry Trade, 5: Monopolistic Competition, B • Under autarky, each country produces and consumes its own varieties. • Opening to trade gives a country access to more varieties: • Even identical countries will now trade, in fact, there will be pure IIT. • Countries which differ in endowments will have: • Inter-industry trade based on endowments; and • Intra-Industry trade based on the preference for variety.
Explaining Intra-Industry Trade, 5: Monopolistic Competition, C • The intra-industry trade creates additional sources of gain from trade: • Lower prices for consumers: If existing producers increase output, their average costs will fall, and monopolistic competition ensures that this will lead to lower prices; and • Increased varieties: which directly increase welfare.
Explaining Intra-Industry Trade, 5: Monopolistic Competition, D • We have been considering trade in varieties of consumer goods, but a large share of trade is in differentiated intermediate goods • The equivalent of a preference for variety is increased division of labor yielding macroeconomic (external) economies of scale. • Adam Smith: Division of labor limited by the extent of the market; • Allyn Young: Greater roundaboutness in production; • Formalized by Wilfred Ethier.
Explaining Intra-Industry Trade, 5: Monopolistic Competition, E • Models including both a HOS and a monopolistic competition basis for trade perform quite well empirically. • Whether monopolistic competition is based on preference for variety or division of labor, there are additional sources of gains from trade. • However, it should be noted that, especially with trade based on monopolistically competitive division of labor, the external economies of scale permit: • Gains from an active trade policy; and • Potential losses from trade
IIT and Economic Adjustment • It has been widely hypothesized that increases in IIT cause less pressure for adjustment than an equivalent increase in inter-industry trade. • This is an empirically plausible hypothesis • Informal evidence seems broadly supportive, but • Systematic empirical evidence is very weak, and • Recent research suggests that the theoretical foundations of this claim are rather weak as well.
Trade and Geography, 1 • Research on international trade has long had direct connections with economic geography. • Ohlin in particular was well-aware of the links • Northern European economic geographers were interested in international trade. • What is distinctive about contemporary work is an interest in the endogenous emergence of economic structure. • In particular, endogenous agglomeration is a central interest.
Trade and Geography, 2 • Endogenous agglomeration emerges in the interaction of: • Internal economies of scale (in varieties); • External (macroeconomic) economies of scale, and • Frictional costs (tariffs, transportation, etc.)
Trade and Geography, 3 • Endogenous Cores and Peripheries • Over time, frictional costs have fallen from very high to very low. • In the very high frictional cost regime, economic activity was relatively evenly spread in space; • As costs fell, local agglomerations arose to take advantage of economies of scale; but • As costs fall further, peripheries rise at the expense of cores in response to diseconomies.
Justifying Trade Policy: Two Dimensions • Economic v. Noneconomic justifications: • Economic justifications for policy intervention emphasize the capacity for such intervention to improve the efficiency of the market. • This implies that there is some distortion that causes the market equilibrium under free competition to diverge from the socially optimal outcome • Non-economic justifications for policy intervention are related to goals other than economic efficiency that might be pursued via intervention in the economy.
Justifying Trade Policy: Two Dimensions (continued) • First-best v. Second (nth)-best justifications: • An argument which demonstrates that trade intervention is the best (i.e. most efficient) way to achieve a policy goal (economic or non-economic) is a "first-best" argument for trade intervention • An argument which demonstrates that, although it is not first-best, trade intervention can achieve a particular policy goal and raise welfare is a second-best (or nth-best) argument for intervention.
Theory of Policy, 1:Identifying the Distortion • What is a “distortion”? • An undistorted small economy is characterized by: • In a distorted economy, at least one of these equalities fails to hold • Some examples of distortions: • Production Externalities: MRSij= p≠ MRTij; • Domestic Monopoly: MRSij≠ p= MRTij; • Non-Operation on PPF: factor market distortion
Theory of Policy, 2:Comparing Policy Instruments • Tariffs and Tax-cum-subsidy Policies • The effects of a tariff can be replicated by a production subsidy and a consumption tax at the same ad valorem rate; • The effects of an export subsidy can be replicated by a production tax and a consumption subsidy at the same ad valorem rate. • This means that the production and consumption effects of a tariff can be separated. • Lerner Symmetry Theorem: An import tariff and an export tax, at the same ad valorem rate, have equivalent economic effects.
Theory of Policy 3:Instrument Ranking • Theorem: When responding to distortions in the economy, the policy interventions that do this may be welfare ranked. • Theorem: When responding to distortions in the economy, the optimal (least cost) method of doing this is to choose the intervention that operates most directly on the relevant distortion.
International Oligopoly and Strategic Trade Policy, 1 • We have already considered international oligopoly as a possible explanation for intra-industry trade, now we consider it as a justification for strategic trade policy. • Consider the following simple model • Symmetric national monopolists in each of two countries (i.e. a global oligopoly). • Contra the text, suppose constant returns to scale. • The oligopolistic good is only exported to a third market (i.e. no consumption in the home markets).
International Oligopoly and Strategic Trade Policy, 2 • In this framework, it is straightforward to show that an export subsidy transfers profits from the Foreign oligopolist to the Home oligopolist. • This is usually called a rent shifting argument for trade policy; • The gain in profit can be shown to exceed the cost of the subsidy and, because there is no home consumption, there is no consumption effect to consider. • This is a first-best policy from a national point of view.
International Oligopoly and Strategic Trade Policy, 3 • Consider the following simple version of the above model in which: • Two firms • An incumbent: Canada’s Bombardier; and • A potential entrant: Brazil’s Embraer. • If Embraer enters the market and Bombardier stays, both will lose 10; • If only one firms produces, that firm will earn a profit of 25. • Non-Cooperative game under Nash equilibrium
International Oligopoly and Strategic Trade Policy, 6 • The previous analysis argues for an export subsidy. • If we suppose that both firms compete in the Home market, there is now a strategic trade policy justification for a tariff on imports: • A tariff will shift rents from the Foreign to the Home firm; but • If there are increasing returns to scale in production, a tariff will even function as export support. • Increased output allows the Home firm to reduce average costs • This makes the Home firm more competitive in export markets • We now need to take into account the effect on Home consumers.
International Oligopoly and Strategic Trade Policy, 7 • Effect on Consumers • In most cases home consumers will consume the good • As a result, consumption effects need to be included in the policy calculation. • Informational problems • Firms have the relevant information, but • They have an incentive to lie. • With too big a subsidy, there is not national gain (though of course the firm gains). • National Oligopoly: Tradeoff between intra-national and inter-national externalities • General equilibrium effects: Subsidies to one industry will draw resources from other industries
International Oligopoly and Strategic Trade Policy, 8 • Very few industries satisfy the—rather stringent—conditions required for a successful strategic trade policy. • A wide variety of industries have been studied. • The only obvious case where such policy can be successful is in aerospace. • In the other cases, this ends up looking like a fancy argument for a corporate handout. • In cases like aerospace the potential for trade war is large. (what determines order of moves?) • As a result, interest in this sort of argument seems to have waned.
External Economies of Scale, 1 • Externalities (“spillovers”) exist when utility functions or production functions are characterized by interdependence. • Interindustrial externalities: production in one industry affects production in another y1 = f1(K1,L1) and y2 = f2(K2,L2; y1) • Intraindustrial externalities: output by one firm in a sector increases productivity of all firms in the sector. y1 = f 1(K1,L1; y1) and y2 = f2(K2,L2).
External Economies of Scale, 2 • Externalities may be positive or negative • Negative externalities: spillovers reduce productivity—e.g. pollution. • Positive externalities: spillovers increase productivity—e.g. worker training, learning, etc. • From an efficiency point of view, positive (negative) externalities will generally be under (over) –priced, and under (over) –produced. • That is, externalities are an example of market failure: That is, the market fails to deliver the optimal quantity of output. • In this case, there is a divergence between private and social returns to activity in the sector with the production externality.
External Economies of Scale, 3 • For concreteness, suppose that sector S produces a positive externality • This means that the market undervalues output from sector S • This, in turn, means that too little of good S is produced • The optimal response is to subsidize output of the S sector.
Trade and External Economies of Scale • Geographical concentration may be self-reinforcing: an initial small move toward clustering may cause a chain reaction, resulting in industrial agglomeration • Examples: Aerospace manufacturing firms in Seattle and Southern California regions. • If the possession of the IRS sector yields higher national income, there may be benefits from an active industrial policy.
Industrial Policy • Industrial policy– a government’s policy designed to create new industries or support existing industries • Industrial policies seek to alter the country´s comparative advantage by picking winners and losers • To the extent that there will be winners and losers, such policy might well produce trade conflict among countries.
Industrial Policy and Market Failure • Market failure is a major justification for industrial policies • Knowledge spillover, for example, is cited as a reason for industrial policies: a certain industry can spread knowledge about new products and processes, making social returns greater than private returns • Similar spillovers occur in research and development (R&D) • Actually proving the existence of market failures in specific cases has proved quite difficult.
Industrial Policy Tools • Uruguay Round and WTO prohibit subsidies for competitive policies • However, governments can use other policies: providing information about foreign markets to domestic firms, helping negotiate contracts, lobbying foreign governments to adopt home country standards, or tying foreign aid to purchases from domestic firms