540 likes | 693 Views
Political economy Government growth. Today: How do people vote in a democracy? Why did the government grow so much in the 20 th century?. Democracy. Political decision making is important for public finance Two types of democracy in this “mini-lecture” Direct Indirect, or representative.
E N D
Political economyGovernment growth Today: How do people vote in a democracy? Why did the government grow so much in the 20th century?
Democracy • Political decision making is important for public finance • Two types of democracy in this “mini-lecture” • Direct • Indirect, or representative
Direct democracy • There are different ways to make decisions in a direct democracy • Unanimity, especially of public goods purchases • Lindahl prices • Majority voting rules • Possible cycling with three or more choices • Median voter theorem • Arrow’s impossibility theorem
Unanimity with public goods • Suppose there are two people trying to find the efficient level of public goods purchases • Each person could decide on a quantity to purchase • Free-rider problem • Each person could decide on a quantity to purchase, given what fraction he or she would pay • The share paid is known as a Lindahl price See also Figure 6.1, p. 107: Notice that by construction of graph, shares add up to one at each point
Feasibility of unanimity rules • Reaching equilibrium • Time and negotiation costs are usually very high when many people are involved • Strategic behavior • One person could react to how he or she thinks the other will behave • Strategic behavior can prevent efficient results from occurring
Majority voting rules • Majority voting relies on all voters having single-peaked preferences • With single-peaked preferences… • The person with median preferences can essentially make the decision (under certain conditions) • Trading votes may or may not increase welfare • Programs that lower overall welfare are known as “pork”
Preferences • When at least one person does not have single-peaked preferences, we can get cycling • Cycling occurs when no clear winner can be established • See also Figure 6.2, p. 110 • Brad and Angela have single-peaked preferences • Jen has double-peaked preferences
Each person has single-peaked preferences here Brad’s peak is at A Jen’s peak is at C Angelina’s peak is at B A vs. B: B wins A vs. C: C wins B vs. C: B wins B is the clear winner Single-peaked preferences
This example is different from the previous one Jen now has double-peaked preferences A and C are both peaks We now get cycling A vs. B: A wins A vs. C: C wins B vs. C: B wins No clear winner This inconsistency is part of a voting paradox Back to Jen’s two peaks This example is the same as in the graph a few slides ago
Agenda manipulation: Someone can decide on the order of votes to get her or his first choice Suppose Angelina decides the order of votes to get her most-desired choice First, A vs. C: C wins Second, B vs. C: B wins B is implemented Suppose Angelina is in charge
The median voter theorem • When preferences of each person are single peaked, we can assign a “median voter” • Relative to the median voter • Half of the people want more • Half of the people want less • Under certain conditions, the median voter’s preferences will be approved
The median voter theorem Median voter theorem predicts that $1,100 will be voted on
Six reasonable criteria for decision making • Kenneth Arrow studied six criteria that many people would consider “ethically acceptable” • Unfortunately, there is no guarantee that all six criteria can be followed • This proof is known as Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem • What are the six criteria? Kenneth Arrow, 2004
The six criteria that Arrow proposed • It can produce a decision whatever the configuration of voters' preferences • No problems due to multipeaked preferences • It must be able to rank all possible outcomes • It must be responsive to individuals’ preferences • Example: If everyone prefers A to B, then society does too • Preferences must be transitive • If A is at least as good as B, and B is at least as good as C, then A is at least as good as C • Independence of irrelevant alternatives • Relative rankings of two goods do not depend on a third good • Dictatorship ruled out • Social welfare is a function of more than one person
Representative democracy • In a representative democracy, a subset of the population votes to determine who our elected politicians are • Median voter theorem applies here also, assuming single-dimensional rankings and exactly two candidates • Ideology, personality, and leadership abilities of the politician may matter to voters • If no candidate appeals to a voter he or she may not vote
0 Median voter theorem in one dimension Number of Voters If a candidate takes position S, the opponent can take the median voter stance and get a majority of the votes Liberal Conservative Median voter S
Implications of the median voter model • Based on the median voter model… • Two-party systems tend to be stable • Replacement of direct referenda by representative system has no effect on outcomes
Logrolling • Logrolling is the act of politicians trading votes in order to pass legislation that is beneficial to their district • Some logrolling improves welfare • Some logrolling does not improve welfare • An example • Suppose that Waldo, Xavier, and Zach each live in a different congressional district • Note that this example uses a different approach than in the book
Logrolling • In each case, Waldo, Xavier, and Zach’s representatives can get together to try to pass each other’s projects • If all three projects are passed together, Waldo, Xavier, and Zach are each better off • Whether or not the logrolling leads to welfare improvements depends on the cost to others
Public employees • Public employees fulfill legislated mandates and operate many government operatives • Bureaucrats sometimes have interpretive power • Red tape criticism • Unresponsive to reasonable requests • No market-oriented incentives • Some bureaucrats want to maximize the size of their departments • Niskanen’s model of bureaucracy • See also Figure 6.4, p. 120
What can the politician do? • A politician can change the quantity to Q* if he or she knows what Q* is • Sometimes, only the bureaucrat knows what Q* is • Make bureaucrats’ pay dependent on quality of work • Requires costly oversight • Hire bureaucrats that are reliable in determining what Q* is • Probably difficult
Special interests • “Special interests” has become a politically-charged term in today’s political arena • What are some special interest groups? • Labor groups • Groups that favor the rich, poor, young, or old • Groups that favor tax breaks for an industry • Groups that want to enhance social and religious goals • Rent-seeking behavior • Attempts for a firm to have positive economic profits
Rent-seeking behavior • See Figure 6.5, p. 122 • Economic rents can be received if the government spurs competition • Positive economic profits • Note deadweight loss
Other people involved • Other people help to carve the political landscape • Judges have control to enforce and interpret laws • Media influence • Providing information • Political leanings • Experts • Former politicians • Example: Al Gore
Summary: Democracy • Democracies can be direct or indirect • Both types of democracies have their own sets of problems • Direct democracies • Time consuming to people • Cycling • Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem • Indirect democracies • Bureaucrats • Special interests
Growth of government spending • Many western countries have had significant growth in government spending since 1900 • How is this growth justified? • Many theories examined • No single theory fully explains the growth • Can government growth be controlled?
Explaining Government Growth • Five theories of government growth • Citizen preferences • Marxist view • Chance events • Changes in social attitudes • Income redistribution
Citizen preferences • Take the median voter’s preferences of public sector goods and services • G = f(P, I) • G represents the median voter’s demand for public sector goods and services • P is the relative price of public sector goods and services • I is income
Citizen preferences • Assume median voter theorem is true • When income increases, if income elasticity of demand is greater than one for the median voter, increased public services would be provided • Growth of the middle class may explain why government spending has grown so much • This theory predicts that voters get what they want
Marxist view • A Marxist model would argue that the private sector overproduces • Government must expand expenditures to correct this • Worker discontent is curbed by social service spending • Some argue that this is not sustainable, since expenditures will eventually outpace tax revenue capacity • See Figure 18.6, p. 423, for more on tax revenue capacity
Government shocks • Chance events lead to shocks on the government • These shocks require the government to increase spending substantially • Examples: The Great Depression; the world wars; the financial crisis of 2008-’09 • Inertia increased spending sticks • Special interest groups try to make sure that “their” spending does not go away
Changes in social attitudes • Are people making bigger demands on government? • Maybe • Due to median voter theorem? • Costs and benefits may also be incorrectly perceived by the public
Income redistribution • Two views • Government grows to help low-income voters • Some politicians can promise redistribution to median income and below • Incomes above the median get taxed to pay for income redistribution • Government grows to help the middle class • Appeals to voters near median income • With this view, the upper- and lower-income classes pay for the benefit of the middle class
Controlling government growth • Some people believe that government is not too big • Others disagree • If the government is too big, how can we make it smaller? • Change bureaucratic incentives • Change fiscal institutions • Institute constitutional limitations
Recall Niskanen’s model of bureaucracy Bureaucrat often worries about size of department, not what is efficient Financial incentives for cost-cutting could backfire, however Q could be below Q* Private provision may be more efficient Change bureaucratic incentives Figure 6.4, p. 120
Change fiscal institutions • Is the budget-making process undisciplined? • Many people believe so • Congress-imposed solution: Budget Enforcement Act (BEA) of 1990 • Spending and revenue targets are set • The cap can be exceeded when an elaborate set of parliamentary rules are followed • Problems with BEA • Some “emergency” spending is known in advance • 2000 census
Institute constitutional limits • If Congress cannot regulate its own spending, should there be a constitutional amendment that does limit spending? • Most economists believe “no”
Why not to impose constitutional limits • Revenue and spending is usually uncertain until it happens • If tax revenue was overestimated, severe spending cuts would have to occur mid-year • Spending could be forced on states instead • States could be mandated to provide part of Social Security • What would the consequences be if Congress circumvents the law? • Judicially-imposed budget? • Will Congress members be punished?
Summary: Growth of gov’t spending • Although political models have appeal on government spending, they do not fully explain how governments behave • Many people believe that government spending needs more control • BEA and current incentive structure ineffective • No constitutional amendment for balanced budget • Probably goes too far
Problems • Lindahl model • Majority voting • Median voter theorem • Efficient government spending
Lindahl problem • Bill and Hillary have decided to be roommates in Washington DC • They decide to use Lindahl prices to determine the amount of money they will spend on a new sofa • Q represents spending on a new sofa • Bill’s share is SB = 1 – Q/500 • Hillary’s share is SH = 1 – Q/400 • Also note that SB + SH = 1
Lindahl problem • How do you solve this? • 3 equations • 3 unknowns • Plug in first two equations into the third equation • (1 – Q/500) + (1 – Q/400) = 1 • (1 – 4Q/2000) + (1 – 5Q/2000) = 1 • 2 – 9Q/2000 = 1 • 1 = 9Q/2000 • Q = 2000/9 = 222.22
Majority voting problem • 5 members on a city council • 4 options: A, B, C, D • Assume each member will vote no unless specified below • Frank: Will only vote in favor of A • Genevieve: Will vote in favor of B; will vote for A if B is defeated first • Holly: Will definitely vote in favor of B or C if either is voted on; will vote for A if B and C are both defeated first • Ivan: Will definitely vote in favor of A or D if either is voted on; will vote for B if A and D are defeated first • Jacqueline: Will definitely vote in favor of C and D if either is voted on
Majority voting problem • Which projects have a chance?
Majority voting problem • Which projects have a chance? A and B
Majority voting problem • Can we get A to pass? • Yes: Have Frank to control the voting process • Step 1: Vote on B Only Genevieve and Holly will vote in favor • Step 2: Vote on C We know that C will never pass • Step 3: Vote on A Since B and C have both been defeated, Holly will also vote in favor of A
Median voter theorem problem • In Santa Barbara, the distribution of desired spending on beaches in the population is as follows • Normal distribution • Average desired spending is $600,000 per year • Standard deviation is $100,000 per year • If you were a politician running for the Santa Barbara city council, what should your stance on this be?
Median voter theorem problem • What should your stance be? • If you believed the median voter theorem, your stance should be consistent with the median voter • In a normal distribution, the mean and the median are the same • Stance should be to spend $600,000 per year