1 / 35

The Firm: Basics

The Firm: Basics. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell . Overview . The Firm: Basics. The setting. The environment for the basic model of the firm. Input require-ment sets. Isoquants. Returns to scale. Marginal products. The basics of production .

haroun
Download Presentation

The Firm: Basics

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The Firm: Basics MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell

  2. Overview The Firm: Basics The setting The environment for the basic model of the firm Input require-ment sets Isoquants Returns to scale Marginal products

  3. The basics of production  • Some elements needed for an analysis of the firm • Technical efficiency • Returns to scale • Convexity • Substitutability • Marginal products • This is in the context of a single-output firm • ...and assuming a competitive environment • First we need the building blocks of a model

  4. Notation • Quantities • zi • amount of input i z = (z1, z2 , , zm) • input vector q • amount of output For next presentation • Prices • wi • price of input i w = (w1, w2 , , wm) • Input-price vector p • price of output

  5. Feasible production • The basic relationship between output and inputs: • q £ f (z1, z2, , zm ) • single-output, multiple-input production relation The production function • This can be written more compactly as: q £f (z) • Note that we use “£” and not “=” in the relation. Why? • Consider the meaning of f Vector of inputs • f gives the maximum amount of output that can be produced from a given list of inputs distinguish two important cases...

  6. Technical efficiency • Case 1: q =f (z) • The case where production is technically efficient • The case where production is (technically) inefficient • Case 2: q < f (z) Intuition: if the combination (z,q) is inefficient, you can throw away some inputs and still produce the same output

  7. q>f (z) q <f (z) z2 z1 The function  q • The production function • Interior points are feasible but inefficient • Boundary points are feasible and efficient q= f(z) • Infeasible points 0 • We need to examine its structure in detail

  8. Overview The Firm: Basics The setting Input require-ment sets The structure of the production function Isoquants Returns to scale Marginal products

  9. The input requirement set • Pick a particular output level q • Find a feasible input vector z • remember, we must have q £f (z) • Repeat to find all such vectors • Yields the input-requirement set • Z(q) := {z: f (z) ³ q} • The set of input vectors that meet the technical feasibility condition for output q • The shape of Z depends on the assumptions made about production • We will look at four cases First, the “standard” case

  10. q =f (z) The input requirement set • Feasible but inefficient z2 • Feasible and technically efficient • Infeasible points Z(q) q <f (z) q >f (z) z1

  11. z2 q =f (z') q< f (z) q =f (z") z1 Case 1: Z smooth, strictly convex • Pick two boundary points • Draw the line between them • Intermediate points lie in the interior of Z Z(q) • z¢ • Note important role of convexity • A combination of two techniques may produce more output • z² • What if we changed some of the assumptions?

  12. z2 z1 Case 2: Z Convex (but not strictly) • Pick two boundary points • Draw the line between them • Intermediate points lie in Z (perhaps on the boundary) Z(q) • z¢ • z² • A combination of feasible techniques is also feasible

  13. z2 This point is infeasible z1 Case 3: Z smooth but not convex • Join two points across the “dent” • Take an intermediate point • Highlight zone where this can occur Z(q) • in this region there is an indivisibility

  14. z2 z1 Case 4: Z convex but not smooth q =f (z) • Slope of the boundary is undefined at this point

  15. z2 z2 z2 z2 z1 z1 z1 z1 Summary: 4 possibilities for Z Standard case, but strong assumptions about divisibility and smoothness Almost conventional: mixtures may be just as good as single techniques Only one efficient point and not smooth Problems: the dent represents an indivisibility

  16. Overview The Firm: Basics The setting Contours of the production function Input require-ment sets Isoquants Returns to scale Marginal products

  17. Isoquants • Pick a particular output level q • Find the input requirement set Z(q) • The isoquant is the boundary of Z:{ z : f(z) = q } • Think of the isoquant as an integral part of the set Z(q) • If the function f is differentiable at z then the marginal rate of technical substitution is the slope at z: • Where appropriate, use subscript to denote partial derivatives. So fj (z) —— fi (z) ¶f(z) fi(z) :=—— ¶zi . • Gives rate at which you trade off one input against another along the isoquant, maintaining constant q Let’s look at its shape

  18. z2 ° z2 z1 ° z1 Isoquant, input ratio, MRTS • The set Z(q) • A contour of the function  • An efficient point • The input ratio • Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution • Increase the MRTS z2 / z1= constant MRTS21=f1(z)/f2(z) • The isoquant is the boundary of Z • z′ • Input ratio describes one production technique • z° {z: f(z)=q} • MRTS21: implicit “price” of input 1 in terms of 2 • Higher “price”: smaller relative use of input 1

  19. z2 z2 z1 z1 MRTS and elasticity of substitution ∂log(z1/z2) =   ∂log(f1/f2) input-ratio  MRTS    input-ratio MRTS prop change input ratio -  = prop change in MRTS s= ½ s= 2 Responsiveness of inputs to MRTS is elasticity of substitution

  20. Elasticity of substitution z2 • A constant elasticity of substitution isoquant • Increase the elasticity of substitution... structure of the contour map... z1

  21. Homothetic contours • The isoquants • Draw any ray through the origin… z2 • Get same MRTS as it cuts each isoquant z1 O

  22. Contours of a homogeneous function • The isoquants z2 • Coordinates of input z° • Coordinates of “scaled up” input tz° • tz° ° tz2 f (tz) = trf (z) • z° ° z2 trq q z1 O O ° ° tz1 z1

  23. Overview... The Firm: Basics The setting Input require-ment sets Changing all inputs together Isoquants Returns to scale Marginal products

  24. Let's rebuild from the isoquants • The isoquants form a contour map • If we looked at the “parent” diagram, what would we see? • Consider returns to scale of the production function • Examine effect of varying all inputs together: • Focus on the expansion path • q plotted against proportionate increases in z • Take three standard cases: • Increasing Returns to Scale • Decreasing Returns to Scale • Constant Returns to Scale • Let's do this for 2 inputs, one output

  25. Case 1: IRTS • An increasing returns to scale function • Pick an arbitrary point on the surface q • The expansion path… • t>1 implies f(tz)> tf(z) z2 0 • Double inputs and you more than double output z1

  26. Case 2: DRTS • A decreasing returns to scale function q • Pick an arbitrary point on the surface • The expansion path… • t>1 implies f(tz)< tf(z) z2 0 • Double inputs and output increases by less than double z1

  27. Case 3: CRTS • A constant returns to scale function q • Pick a point on the surface • The expansion path is a ray • f (tz) = tf (z) z2 0 • Double inputs and output exactly doubles z1

  28. Relationship to isoquants • Take any one of the three cases (here it is CRTS) q • Take a horizontal “slice” • Project down to get the isoquant • Repeat to get isoquant map z2 0 • The isoquant map is the projection of the set of feasible points z1

  29. Overview  The Firm: Basics The setting Input require-ment sets Changing one input at time Isoquants Returns to scale Marginal products

  30. Marginal products • Pick a technically efficient input vector • Remember, this means a z such that q= f(z) • Keep all but one input constant • Measure the marginal change in output w.r.t. this input • The marginal product ¶f(z) MPi = fi(z) = —— ¶zi.

  31. CRTS production function again q • Now take a vertical “slice” • The resulting path for z2 = constant z2 0 Let’s look at its shape z1

  32. MP for the CRTS function f1(z) • The feasible set q • Technically efficient points f(z) • Slope of tangent is the marginal product of input 1 • Increase z1… • A section of the production function • Input 1 is essential:Ifz1= 0 thenq = 0 • f1(z) falls withz1 (or stays constant) iff is concave z1

  33. q q q z1 z1 z1 q z1 Relationship between q and z1 • We’ve just taken the conventional case • But in general this curve depends on the shape of  • Some other possibilities for the relation between output and one input…

  34. Key concepts Review Review Review Review Review Technical efficiency Returns to scale Convexity MRTS Marginal product

  35. What next? Introduce the market Optimisation problem of the firm Method of solution Solution concepts

More Related