1 / 26

“Cantillon effects” in the market for art

“Cantillon effects” in the market for art. Cameron M. Weber PhD Student, New School for Social Research Adjunct Professor, FIT/SUNY and St. John’s University. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art. Introduction to theory of Cantillon Effects Our case study The model Results.

jaeger
Download Presentation

“Cantillon effects” in the market for art

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art Cameron M. Weber PhD Student, New School for Social Research Adjunct Professor, FIT/SUNY and St. John’s University

  2. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art • Introduction to theory of Cantillon Effects • Our case study • The model • Results

  3. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art Given classical equation of exchange, MV = PQ Adding causality and non-neutrality: Endogenous money, PQ => MV (Hume, Wicksell, Marx) Exogenous money, MV => PQ (Keynes, Monetarist)

  4. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art Disaggregating “Q” into consumption goods and stages of production (time-variant intermediate goods) we get Austrian School use of deviation from ‘natural rates’ of interest and consequently malinvestment and prolonged business cycles

  5. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art Disaggregating and re-theorizing we get money supply effects on both output and assets Cantillon Effects describe increasing asset prices (asset bubbles) coinciding with an increasing exogenous (central bank) money supply Δ M => Δ Asset Prices

  6. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art An example of Cantillon Effects “But in November Naota Kan, who has since become Japan’s finance minister, made what he proudly call his ‘deflationary declaration’, urging the BOJ to redouble its efforts to combat falling prices. Days later the BOJ offered ¥10 trillion ($112 billion) of virtually interest-free liquidity to the banking system to fight deflation….As the yen came off its high, investors piled into shares. But since then the yen has rebounded with barely a squeak from the BOJ” (The Economist, January 30, 2010).

  7. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art Callahan and Garrison 2003 “We believe that events comprising the dot-com boom and bust can be illuminated by tracing the Cantillon effects as new money made its way from the Federal Reserve, through the banking system, and finally to the dot-com start-ups” (68). “As a result, after increasing at a rate of less than 2.5 percent during the first three years of the Clinton administration, MZM (money zero maturity ) increased over the next three years (1996-1998) at an annualized rate of over 10%, rising during the last half of 1998 at a binge rate of almost 15 percent” (81). Callahan, G. & Garrison R.W. (2003). Does Austrian business cycle theory help explain the dot-com boom and bust? Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 6(2), 67-98.

  8. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art “Emerging signs of stronger economic activity and the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)’s second round of quantitative easing (QE2) have raised concern among some analysts that expansionary policy might be causing bubbles in financial and commodity markets— bubbles that might harm the economy if they burst. Prices for bonds, equities, and commodities have increased sharply since late August: The Reuters Jefferies/CRB weekly futures commodity price index increased by 22 percent (in U.S. dollars) through the week of November 9 (but fell sharply the following week), oil prices by 22 percent, the Economist food-price index by 20 percent, the Russell 2000 Index by 22 percent, and the broader S&P 500 Index by 15 percent (see charts). Given these increases, the concern over bubbles is reasonable, but it is difficult to distinguish beforehand the line between aggressive (“just right”) monetary policy and overly aggressive (“too hot”) monetary policy that generates bubbles. Rapid increases in commodity and financial market prices by themselves, however, are not reliable indicators of potential bubbles because such increases also occur as part of normal monetary policy.” Anderson, R.G. (2011). Monetary Policy, Bubbles, and Goldilocks, Economic Synopsis, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, January 13.

  9. Our case study The use of fine art might be an effective means to measure Cantillon Effects as art is removed from the capital structure of the economy, so we might be able to measure “pure” Cantillon Effects. In other words, the “Q” value in the classical equation of exchange is missing all together for the causal chain, thus an increase in the money supply might be seen to directly effect the price of art. Economic theory is that as money supply increases, the “time-preferences” of art investors decreases (art becomes cheaper relative to consumption goods) and/or inflationary expectations mean that art investors see price signals (“easy money”) encouraging investment in art.

  10. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art Art data based on 1,336 repeated sales from 1830 – 2007 on the London market. Data provided by Goetzmann et al 2010, data commonly used by cultural economists to measure returns to art versus other assets, updated by Goetzmann et al for error correction, contemporary art (1960s onward) and a more recent method for inflation indexing. Goetzmann W., Renneboog L. & Spaenjers C. (2010). Art and money. NBER Working Paper 15502

  11. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art Money supply is “M1” based on methodology used by Bessler 1984 and Devadoss & Meyers 1987, in order to compare results of Cantillon Effects versus money supply effects on output prices. Bessler, D.A. (1984). Relative prices and money: A vector autoregression on Brazilian data. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 66 (1), 25-30. Devadoss S. & Meyers W.H. (1987). Relative prices and money: Further results for the United States. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 69 (4), 838-842.

  12. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art

  13. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art We find two distinct periods of monetary history, leading to the need for data bifurcation between the pre-war Classical Gold Standard (1830 – 1913) and the post-war central-banking era (1946 - 2007).

  14. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art

  15. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art H0 :A change in money supply does not “Granger Cause” a change in the art index in the same in the direction H1 :A change in money supply “Granger Causes” a change in the art index in the same in the direction

  16. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art

  17. “Cantillon effects” in the market for artLong-term Relationships

  18. “Cantillon effects” in the market for artShort-term Relationships Following Goetzmann et al (2010) we conduct a comovement analysis to determine the “short-term”, year-to-year, relationships between the variables, to supplement the “long-term” correlations. We use first differences (∆) in each variable to capture the year-to-year differences in the short-term analysis, although do not extend the analysis to lagged first differences beyond a single period following McCallum (2010) who recommends a one-lag model in case of “serious” autoregression.

  19. “Cantillon effects” in the market for artRegression Analysis Following McCallum 2010 we use a least squares regression, with independent variables of a one-period lag for our general and robustness check models, and correct for heteroskedasticity to cleanse the error terms of autocorrelation which as noted in Table 2 (“Correlations”) we highly-suspect. McCallum, B.T. (2010). Is the Spurious Regression Problem Spurious? NBER Working Paper 15690.

  20. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art We are not able to reject the null hypothesis that there is no Granger causality between money supply changes and art price changes.

  21. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art Bessler 1984 and Devadoss & Meyers 1987 use a VAR log likelihood model to estimate the most likely lagtimes between a monetary change and effects on output prices. They find (using monthly data) that the most likely lagtime is 13 and 14 months with a rapidly dissipation of the price increase immediately following the most likely effect.

  22. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art Using the same methodology we find that the most likely effect of a money supply change on art prices is also between the 13th and 23rd month (e.g., during the 2nd year using yearly data). However, unlike the earlier work on output prices, we find that the effect on art prices does not decay rapidly after the monetary increase, showing perhaps that money changes are cumulative (and/or have momentum) and could lead to an ‘asset bubble’.

  23. “Cantillon effects” in the market for artNon-Decaying money effect on asset values

  24. “Cantillon effects” in the market for artDecaying money effect on output prices Bessler, D.A. (1984). Relative prices and money: A vector autoregression on Brazilian data. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 66 (1), 25-30.

  25. “Cantillon effects” in the market for art Thank you

More Related