500 likes | 780 Views
Presentation Highlights. Paper has two new contributions:Extendible maturity framework for real optionsUse of jump-reversion process for oil pricesPresentation of the model:Petroleum investment model Concepts for options with extendible maturitiesThresholds for immediate investment and for ext
E N D
1. Petroleum Concessions with Extendible Options Using Mean Reversion with Jumps to Model Oil Prices By: Marco A. G. Dias (Petrobras) & Katia M. C. Rocha (IPEA) .
3rd Annual International Conference on Real Options - Theory Meets Practice
Wassenaar/Leiden, The Netherlands
June 1999
2. Presentation Highlights Paper has two new contributions:
Extendible maturity framework for real options
Use of jump-reversion process for oil prices
Presentation of the model:
Petroleum investment model
Concepts for options with extendible maturities
Thresholds for immediate investment and for extension
Jump + mean-reversion process for oil prices
Topics: systematic jump, discount rate, convenience yield
C++ software interactive interface
Base case and sensibility analysis
Alternative timing policies for Brazilian National Agency
Concluding remarks
3. E&P Is a Sequential Options Process Drill the pioneer? Wait? Extend?
Revelation, option-game: waiting incentives
4. Economic Quality of a Developed Reserve Concept by Dias (1998): q = ?V/?P
q = economic quality of the developed reserve
V = value of the developed reserve ($/bbl)
P = current petroleum price ($/bbl)
For the proportional model, V = q P, the economic quality of the reserve is constant. We adopt this model.
The option charts F x V and F x P at the expiration (t = T)
5. The Extendible Maturity Feature
6. Options with Extendible Maturity Options with extendible maturities was studied by Longstaff (1990) for financial applications
We apply the extendible option framework for petroleum concessions.
The extendible feature occurs in Brazil and Europe
Base case of 5 years plus 3 years by paying a fee K (taxes and/or additional exploratory work).
Included into model: benefit recovered from the fee K
Part of the extension fee can be used as benefit (reducing the development investment for the second period, D2)
At the first expiration, there is a compound option (call on a call) plus a vanilla call. So, in this case extendible option is more general than compound one
7. Extendible Option Payoff at the First Expiration At the first expiration (T1), the firm can develop the field, or extend the option, or give-up/back to govern
For geometric Brownian motion, the payoff at T1 is:
8. Poisson-Gaussian Stochastic Process We adapt the Merton (1976) jump-diffusion idea but for the oil prices case:
Normal news cause only marginal adjustment in oil prices, modeled with a continuous-time process
Abnormal rare news (war, OPEC surprises,...) cause abnormal adjustment (jumps) in petroleum prices, modeled with a discrete time Poisson process
Differences between our model and Merton model:
Continuous time process: mean-reversion instead the geometric Brownian motion (more logic for oil prices)
Uncertainty on the jumps size: two truncated normal distributions instead the lognormal distribution
Extendible American option instead European vanilla
Jumps can be systematic instead non-systematic
9. Stochastic Process Model for Oil Prices Model has more economic logic (supply x demand)
Normal information causes smoothing changes in oil prices (marginal variations) and means both:
Marginal interaction between production and demand (inventory levels is an indicator); and
Depletion versus new reserves discoveries (the ratio of reserves/production is an indicator)
Abnormal information means very important news:
In a short time interval, this kind of news causes a large variation (jumps) in the prices, due to large variation (or expected large variation) in either supply or demand
Mean-reversion has been considered a better model than GBM for commodities and perhaps for interest rates and for exchange rates. Why?
Economic logic; term structure of futures prices; volatility of futures prices; spot prices econometric tests
10. Nominal Prices for Brent and Similar Oils (1970-1999)
11. Equation for Mean-Reversion + Jumps The stochastic equation for the petroleum prices (P) Geometric Mean-Reversion with Random Jumps is:
12. Mean-Reversion and Jumps for Oil Prices The long-run mean or equilibrium level which the prices tends to revert P is hard to estimate
Perhaps a game theoretic model, setting a leader-follower duopoly for price-takers x OPEC and allies
A future upgrade for the model is to consider P as stochastic and positively correlated with the prices level P
Slowness of a reversion: the half-life (H) concept
Time for the price deviations from the equilibrium-level are expected to decay by half of their magnitude. H = ln(2)/(h P )
The Poisson arrival parameter l (jump frequency), the expected jump sizes, and the sizes uncertainties.
We adopt jumps as rare events (low frequency) but with high expected size. So, we looking to rare large jumps (even with uncertain size).
Used 1 jump for each 6.67 years, expecting doubling P (in case of jump-up) or halving P (in case of jump-down).
Let the jump risk be systematic, so is not possible to build a riskless portfolio as in Merton (1976). We use dynamic programming
13. Dynamic Programming and Options
14. A Motivation for Using Dynamic Programming First, see the contingent claims PDE version of this model:
15. Boundary Conditions
16. The C++ Software Interface: Main Window
17. The C++ Software Interface: Progress Calculus Window
18. Main Results Window
19. Parameters Values for the Base Case The more complex stochastic process for oil prices (jump-reversion) demands several parameters estimation
The criteria for the base case parameters values were:
Looking values used in literature (others related papers)
Half-life for oil prices ranging from less than a year to 5 years
For drift related parameters, is better a long time series than a large number of samples (Campbell, Lo & MacKinlay, 1997 )
Looking data from an average oilfield in offshore Brazil
Oilfield currently with NPV = 0; Reserves of 100 millions barrels
Preliminary estimative of the parameters using dynamic regression (adaptative model), with the variances of the transition expressions calculated with Bayesian approach using MCMC (Markov Chain Monte Carlo)
Large number of samples is better for volatility estimation
Several sensibility analysis were performed, filling the gaps
20. Jump-Reversion Base Case Parameters
21. The First Option and the Payoff Note the smooth pasting of option curve on the payoff line
The blue curve (option) is typical for mean reversion cases
22. The Two Payoffs for Jump-Reversion
23. The Options and Payoffs for Both Periods
24. Options Values at T1 and Just After T1
25. The Thresholds Charts for Jump-Reversion
26. Alternatives Timing Policies for Petroleum Sector The table presents the sensibility analysis for different timing policies for the petroleum sector
Option values are proxy for bonus in the bidding
Higher thresholds means more investment delay
Longer timing means more bonus but more delay (tradeoff)
Results indicate a higher % gain for option value (bonus) than a % increase in thresholds (delay)
So, is reasonable to consider something between 8-10 years
27. Alternatives Timing Policies for Petroleum Sector The first draft of the Brazilian concession timing policy, pointed 3 + 2 = 5 years
The timing policy was object of a public debate in Brazil, with oil companies wanting a higher timing
In April/99, the notable economist and ex-Finance Minister Delfim Netto defended a longer timing policy for petroleum sector using our paper:
In his column from a top Brazilian newspaper (Folha de São Paulo), he commented and cited (favorably) our paper conclusions about timing policies to support his view!
The recent version of the concession contract (valid for the 1st bidding) points up to 9 years of total timing, divided into two or three periods
So, we planning an upgrade of our program to include the cases with three exploration periods
28. Comparing Dynamic Programming with Contingent Claims Results show very small differences in adopting non-arbitrage contingent claims or dynamic programming
However, for geometric Brownian motion the difference is very large
29. Sensibility Analysis: Jump Frequency Higher jump frequency means higher hysteresis: higher investment threshold P* and lower extension threshold PE
30. Sensibility Analysis: Volatility
31. Comparing Jump-Reversion with GBM Is the use of jump-reversion instead GBM much better for bonus (option) bidding evaluation?
Is the use of jump-reversion significant for investment and extension decisions (thresholds)?
Two important parameters for these processes are the volatility and the convenience yield d.
In order to compare option value and thresholds from these processes in the same basis, we use the same d
In GBM, d is an input, constant, and let d = 5%p.a.
For jump-reversion, d is endogenous, changes with P, so we need to compare option value for a P that implies d = 5%:
32. Comparing Jump-Reversion with GBM
33. Concluding Remarks The paper main contributions are:
Use of the options with extendible maturities framework for real assets, allowing partial recovering of the extension fee K
We use a more rigourous and more logic but more complex stochastic process for oil prices (jump-reversion)
The main upgrades planned for the model:
Inclusion of a third period (another extendible expiration), for several cases of the new Brazilian concession contract
Improvement on the stochastic process, by allowing the long-run mean P to be stochastic and positively correlated
First time a real options paper cited in Brazilian important newspaper
Comparing with GBM, jump-reversion presents:
Higher options value (higher bonus); higher thresholds for short lived options (concessions) and lower for long lived one
34. Additional Materials for Support
35. Demonstration of the Jump-Reversion PDE Consider the Bellman for the extendible option (up T1):
36. Finite Difference Method Numerical method to solve numerically the partial differential equation (PDE)
The PDE is converted in a set of differences equations and they are solved iteratively
There are explicit and implicit forms
Explicit problem: convergence problem if the “probabilities” are negative
Use of logaritm of P has no advantage for mean-reverting
Implicit: simultaneous equations (three-diagonal matrix). Computation time (?)
Finite difference methods can be used for jump-diffusions processes. Example: Bates (1991)
37. Explicit Finite Difference Form Grid: Domain space DP x Dt
Discretization F(P,t) º F( iDP, jDt ) º Fi, j
With 0 £ i £ m and 0 £ j £ n
where m = Pmax/DP and n = T / Dt
38. Finite Differences Discretization The derivatives approximation by differences are the central difference for P, and foward-difference for t:
FPP » [ F i+1,j - 2Fi,j + Fi-1,j ] / (DP)2 FP » [ F i+1,j - Fi-1,j ] / 2DP
Ft » [ F i,j+1 - Fi,j ] / Dt
Substitutes the aproximations into the PDE
39. Economic Quality of a Developed Reserve
40. Sensibility analysis show that the options values increase in case of:
Increasing the reversion speed h (or decreasing the half-life H);
Decreasing the risk-adjusted discount rate r, because it decreases also d, due the relation r = h(P - P) + d , increasing the waiting effect;
Increasing the volatility s do processo de reversão;
Increasing the frequency of jumps l;
Increasing the expected value of the jump-up size;
Reducing the cost of the extension of the option K;
Increasing the long-run mean price P;
Increasing the economic quality of the developed reserve q; and
Increasing the time to expiration (T1 and T2) Others Sensibility Analysis
41. Sensibility Analysis: Reversion Speed
42. Sensibility Analysis: Discount Rate r
43. Estimating the Discount Rate with Market Data A practical “market” way to estimate the discount rate r in order to be not so arbitrary, is by looking d with the futures market contracts with the longest maturity (but with liquidity)
Take both time series, for d (calculated from futures) and for the spot price P.
With the pair (P, d) estimate a time series for r using the equation: r(t) = d (t) + h[P - P (t)].
This time series (for r) is much more stable than the series for d. Why? Because d and P has a high positive correlation (between +0.809 to 0.915, in the Schwartz paper of 1997) .
An average value for r from this time series is a good choice for this parameter
OBS: This method is different of the contingent claims, even using the market data for r
44. Sensibility Analysis: Lon-Run Mean
45. Sensibility Analysis: Time to Expiration
46. Sensibility Analysis: Economic Quality of Reserve
47. Geometric Brownian Base Case
48. Drawbacks from the Model The speed of the calculation is very sensitive to the precision. In a Pentium 133 MHz:
Using DP = 0.5 $/bbl takes few minutes; but using more reasonable DP = 0.1, takes two hours!
The point is the required Dt to converge (0.0001 or less)
Comparative statics takes lot of time, and so any graph
Several additional parameters to estimate (when comparing with more simple models) that is not directly observable.
More source of errors in the model
But is necessary to develop more realistic models!
49. The Grid Precision and the Results
50. Software Interface: Data Input Window