600 likes | 626 Views
Debt and Debt Crises. Ugo Panizza UNCTAD. There are my own views. The standard view. Facts Countries get into debt problems because of lax fiscal policies Countries have an incentive to default on their external debt obligations Policies
E N D
Debt and Debt Crises Ugo Panizza UNCTAD There are my own views
The standard view • Facts • Countries get into debt problems because of lax fiscal policies • Countries have an incentive to default on their external debt obligations • Policies • Debt crises should always be followed by a fiscal retrenchment • We need to implement policies that reduce a country's incentive to default
Background • U. Panizza, F. Sturzenegger, and J. Zettelmeyer (2009) "The Economics and Law of Sovereign Debt and Sovereign Default" Journal of Economic Literature • B. Eichengreen, R. Hausmann, and U. Panizza (2003) “The Pain of Original Sin” University of Chicago Press • E. Borensztein, and U. Panizza (2009)"The Costs of Sovereign Default" IMF Staff Papers • E. Levy Yeyati and U. Panizza (2010) "The Elusive Cost of Sovereign Default," Journal of Development Economics • E. Borensztein, E. Levy Yeyati, and U. Panizza (2006) Living with Debt, Harvard University Press and IDB • C. Campos, D. Jaimovich, and U. Panizza (2006) “The Unexplained Part of Public Debt,” Emerging Markets Review
Outline • Facts • How debt grows • When do countries borrow and default • Policies • Avoiding debt explosions • What to do during debt crises • How to deal with defaults
How Debt Grows? • The economics 101 debt accumulation equation states that: • CHANGE IN DEBT = DEFICIT • Practitioners use: • CHANGE IN DEBT = DEFICIT+SF • SF=Stock-flow reconciliation, or the unexplained part of public debt • The stock-flow reconciliation is often considered a residual entity of small importance • Is it?
If we estimate: We expect: band R2 to be close to 1 and a = 0 R-Squared Source: Campos, Jaimovich and Panizza (2006)
The Unexplained Part of Public Debt Source: Campos, Jaimovich and Panizza (2006)
The Unexplained Part of Public Debt • The growth rate of the debt-to-GDP ratio is equal to: • Primary deficit/GDP + interest payments/GDP+ – GDP growth – inflation • The last two variables are multiplied by the debt-to-GDP ratio • If you like math:
The Unexplained Part of Public Debt 15 10 5 INFLATION GDP GROWTH 0 UNEXPLAINED PART INTEREST EXPENDITURE PRIMARY DEFICIT -5 -10 -15 IND SAS CAR EAP ECA MNA LAC SSA Source: Campos, Jaimovich and Panizza (2006)
The Unexplained Part of Public Debt • What explains the “Unexplained” part of debt • Skeletons • Fiscal policy matters! • Transparent fiscal accounts are important • Banking Crises • Balance Sheet Effects due to debt composition Much more about this in a while
The Unexplained Part of Public Debt • There are also things that we can explain but may not have anything to do with fiscal policy • Output collapses • Sudden jumps in borrowing costs • Natural disasters
Outline • Facts • How debt grows • When do countries borrow and default • Policies • Avoiding debt explosions • What to do during debt crises • How to deal with defaults
Why is sovereign debt special? • Creditor rights are not as well defined for sovereign debt as is the case for private debts. • If a private firm becomes insolvent, creditors have a claim on the company’s assets. • In the case of a sovereign debt, in contrast, the legal recourse available to creditors has limited applicability and uncertain effectiveness. • Sovereign immunity • Little to attach • So, why do countries repay and why do lenders lend?
The Economic Theory of Sovereign Debt • The literature started with (and it's still tied to) an influential theoretical paper by Eaton and Gersovitz (Review of Economic Studies, 1981) • The story of the paper was: • Countries borrow in bad times (low economic growth) and repay in good times (high economic growth) • Since there are no repayments in bad times, there cannot be defaults either • As a consequence, defaults can only happen in good times • Defaults are thus strategic (countries can pay but they decide not to pay) • The only reason that prevents countries from defaulting is that defaults are costly
The Economic Theory of Sovereign Debt • So, what are the costs of default? • The traditional economic literature has emphasized • Reputational costs • Countries that default will no longer be able to access the international capital market • Trade costs • Default will lead to sanctions which, in turn, will have a negative effect on trade
What do the data say? • Government external borrowing is procyclical and not countercyclical (probably because countries borrow when they can) • This confirms the idea that the seeds of debt crises are planted during good times
What do the data say? Default Happen in Waves…. • 1824-1840. 19 events (14 in Latin America: recent independence, civil wars). Long restructuring periods • 1840-1860. 6 events. Credit boom • 1861-1920. 58 events. Much faster restructuring • 1921-1940. 39 events. Great Depression and WWII. • 1941-1970. 6 events (but little lending) • 1971-1981. 15 events. Boom in syndicated bank loans • 1982-1990. 70 events. The “Debt Crisis” • 1991-2004. 40 events. Lending booms and Sudden Stops
…and they are often linked to bad external financial conditions
What do the data say? • 3 years after the resolution of a default episode, there is no statistically significant difference between the spreads paid by defaulters and non defaulters • We find similar results if we look at access • Global factors (risk aversion and US interest rate) appear to be more important than default history
What do the data say? • There is some evidence that defaults have a negative effect on trade • But this is still controversial and the channel is not clear • No evidence that defaults have a direct impact on trade credit • No evidence (at least in recent years) of explicit sanctions
What do the data say? • Anyway, who cares? • We do know that defaults are bad because they lead to deep recessions • Econometric estimates found that, on average, default episodes are associated with a 2 percentage points drop in GDP growth • But do we really know what we think we know? • Are default episodes bad for growth or is it low growth that causes default? • That is, do defaults happen in bad times?
What do the data say? • Causality is always very hard to assess • But, if we look at high frequency data, we find that: • Growth collapses anticipate defaults • Default episodes are often followed by a rapid rebound of the economy
Do countries default too early or too late? • Hell, the last thing I should be doing is tell a country we should give up our claims. But there comes a time when you have to face reality. • Unnamed financial industry official. Both are taken (Source: Bluestein, 2005, p 163) • The problem historically has not been that countries have been too eager to renege on their financial obligations, but often too reluctant. • Memo prepared by the Central Banks of England and Canada (Source: Bluestein, 2005, p 102)
Political costs of default • There is a (small) literature of political costs of currency devaluations (Cooper 1971). • Frankel (2005) finds that a devaluation increases turnover of finance ministers from 36 to 58 percent. • Applying Frankel’s approach, bond defaults increase minister turnover from 19 to 40 percent. But bank defaults increase it only to 24 percent. • Governments lose votes after defaults • The high political cost of default may affect the timing of the decision by the government. It could cause “gambles for redemption” • Mickey Mouse model (Borensztein and Panizza, 2009)
Summing up: Theory versus Reality • Theory • Countries get into trouble because of lax fiscal policy • Countries borrow in bad times • If ever, countries default in good times (strategic defaults) • So, if anything, they default too much • Defaults are very bad for the economy, with long lasting negative consequences • Reality • Many debt explosions have nothing to do with fiscal policy • Countries borrow in good times • Countries default in bad times (justified defaults) • And sometimes too late • Defaults do not seem to have long lasting negative consequences
Outline • Facts • How debt grows • When do countries borrow and default • Policies • Avoiding debt explosions • What to do during debt crises • How to deal with defaults
Prudent Fiscal Policy • Control the flow of debt • Only borrow when the social return is higher than the opportunity cost of funds • This requires strengthening fiscal policies and institutions • Fiscal rules • Budget institutions • Hierarchical rules • Transparency Rules • Like motherhood and apple pie, this is always good, but it may not be enough
Avoid disasters in the banking sector • It is mostly about preventing lending booms (Borio, Reinhart, Rogoff)
Low debt is not enough Public Debt and Sovereign Rating (1995-2005) Germany United Kingdom Switzerland France Austria Norway AAA Australia Spain Finland Denmark Canada United States Ireland Belgium New Zealand Luxembourg Portugal Japan Italy Sweden Netherlands AA- Iceland Cyprus Saudi Arabia Malta Botswana Slovenia Israel Chile Czech Republic Korea, Rep. Standard & Poor's Sovereign Rating A- Qatar Bahamas Bahrain Barbados Malaysia Estonia Latvia Investment grade Thailand China Hungary Poland Tunisia Oman Trinidad and Tobago South Africa Slovak Republic Egypt, Arab Rep. Lithuania BBB- Mexico El Salvador Panama Croatia Colombia Kazakhstan Peru India Morocco Uruguay Costa Rica Guatemala Philippines BB- Bulgaria Jordan Brazil Senegal Bolivia Russian Federation Mongolia Belize Benin Ghana Ukraine Papua New Guinea Grenada Paraguay Jamaica Venezuela, RB Indonesia Turkey Argentina Pakistan B- Ecuador 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 Public Debt as Percent of GDP Source : Jaimovich and Panizza (2006) and Standard and Poor's
Low debt is not enough Source: De Grauwe (2011)
Low debt is not enough Source: De Grauwe (2011)
The importance of debt structure • Debt denominated in foreign currency or short-maturity debt is associated with: • Lower Credit Ratings • Sudden Stops • Higher volatility • Limited ability of conducting monetary policy • Contractionary devaluations • An appropriate debt structure can reduce risk
How to make debt safer • New and safer instruments • Local currency • Contingent debt instruments • GDP index bonds • Commodity linked bonds • Catastrophe bonds • Dedollarize official lending
Why do we need official intervention? • Market failures • Critical mass • Standards • Instruments cannot be patented • Political economy • Shortsighted politicians may underinsure
Outline • Facts • How debt grows • When do countries borrow and default • Policies • Avoiding debt explosions • What to do during debt crises • How to deal with defaults
Fiscal consolidation? • The instinctive response to a debt crisis is (almost) always: we need a fiscal adjustment • This does not make much sense if the debt crisis is not rooted in fiscal problems • In fact, it may hurt. • Not only in the short-run, but also in the long-run: • Recessions lead to a permanent output loss (Cerra and Saxena, 2008) • The adjustment variable is public investment (Easterly, Irwin, Serven, 2008; Martner and Tromben, 2005)
The adjustment variable is public investment Source: Martner and Tromben (2005)
…and this is very bad for growth, and for the fiscal adjustment When growth-promoting spending is cut so much that the present value of future government revenues falls by more than the immediate improvement in the cash deficit, fiscal adjustment becomes like walking up the down escalator. (Easterly, Irwin, Serven, 2008)
What can the international community do? • Don’t ask for fiscal contractions if fiscal profligacy was not the problem • If a fiscal contractions is needed, don’t frontload it (Blanchard and Cottarelli, 2010) • Think about fiscal targets that protect investment (Blanchard and Giavazzi, 2004, Buiter, 198?) • Also think about the quality of public investment (Pritchett, 2000, Dabla-Norris et al., 2011,)
When is a fiscal contraction needed? • Think hard about the math Dd=-ps+(i-g)d • Multiple equilibria (high i and low i) • The international community can help (especially when the global i is very low) • Don’t lend at punitive interest rates • Bagehot was right for banking crises, but he might be wrong for sovereign debt crises • Moral hazard is often overstated (Meltzer versus Krugman)
Outline • Facts • How debt grows • When do countries borrow and default • Policies • Avoiding debt explosions • What to do during debt crises • How to deal with defaults
From earlier this morning • Theory • Countries borrow in bad times • If ever, countries default in good times (strategic defaults) • So, if anything, they default too much • Defaults are very bad for the economy, with long lasting negative consequences • Reality • Countries borrow in good times • Countries default in bad times (justified defaults) • And sometimes too late • Defaults do not seem to have long lasting negative consequences