1 / 33

Lezione 2 bis

Lezione 2 bis. Differences in technology. The causes of international trade. Now we start to consider the causes of international trade. We will investigate the economic characteristics underlying the pattern of comparative advantage.

jeanine
Download Presentation

Lezione 2 bis

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Lezione 2 bis Differences in technology Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  2. The causes of international trade • Now we start to consider the causes of international trade. We will investigate the economic characteristics underlying the pattern of comparative advantage. • A convenient method to investigate the cause of international trade is to imagine a world in which there is no trade. In terms of our simple model this circumstance occurs when all autarky price ratios are identical and there are no scale economies Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  3. The causes of international trade • In particular, five conditions guarantee the no-trade situation: 1) identical production functions among coutries 2) the same relative endowments in all countries 3) constant returns to scale 4) identical and homogeneous tastes in all countries 5) the absence of distortions (taxes, subsidies, imperfect competition) • If any one of these five conditions is relaxed, then international trade will occur. Therefore, in a reverse way, the five conditions underlying the no-trade situation can be thought of as the principal determinants of international trade. • From a methodological point of view, it is useful to analyse each determinant in isolation through specific models. Now we will focus on differences in technology between countries (differences in production functions) Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  4. A simple model of production function differences • We consider the Ricardian model, a one-factor model in which differences in technology are expressed in terms of differences in labour productivity across countries: the amount of output that can be obtained from one unit of labour differs across countries. • Constant return to scale are assumed. Given that this is a one-factor model, this hypothesis implies a linear production possibility frontier. • The other implication associated with the hyphotesis of a single factor is that the second condition of the five illustrated previously is not relaxed (the same relative endowments in all countries) • We also impose the remaining conditions: no distortions and tastes are identical Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  5. Absolute and comparative advantage • In the model, labour is the only constraint on the production. If the economy produces good X and good Y, we can write the production functions and the labour constraint as: • Under the hypothesis of constant returns to scale, we can express production functions as: Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  6. Absolute and comparative advantage • where and are positive constants and represent the marginal products of labour in industries X and Y respectively • The Ricardian approach based on the concept of comparative advantage is illustrated in the following tables. • In table 1, country H has an absolute advantage in the production of Y: . Country F an absolute advantage in the production of X: • Table 2 shows the possibility of increasing world production of both commodities through specialization Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  7. 2. Changes in outputs due to reallocation of one worker from X to Y in Country H and one worker from Y to X in Country F • Marginal products of labor Home Foreign Home Foreign Total X X –20 +30 +10 Y Y +20 –10 +10 4. Changes in outputs due to reallocation of four workers from X to Y in Country H and one worker from Y to X in Country F 3. Marginal products of labor Home Foreign Home Foreign Total X X –20 +30 +10 Y Y +20 –10 +10 Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  8. Absolute and comparative advantage • Table 3 shows a different situation. Now Country F is more efficient in the production of both goods. Is trade still possible in this new situation? • Yes, because H has a comparative advantage in the production of good Y: (or, equivalently, we can say that H has a relative lower opportunity cost of Y in terms of X) • Table 4 illustrates the existence of gains from specialization and trade also in the case in which a country (in this case, Country F) has an absolute advantage in both productions Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  9. The production possibility frontier • The following figure illustrates the production frontier for country H and F based on the pattern of comparative advantage as reported in the previous table 1 • we denote and the labour endowments in the two countries H and F, respectively. The production frontier for Country H (HH’) has a maximum X output of and a maximum Y output of . The production frontier for Country F (FF’) has a maximum X output of and a maximum Y output of • The slope of a country’s production frontier is: Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  10. Y H Ah F ● Af ● X 0 H’ F’ Production frontier and autarky equilibrium Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  11. The production possibility frontier • The country’s autharky price ratio is given by the slope of its production frontier. But the slope reflects comparative advantage. Therefore autarky prices reflect comparative advantage • The following diagram shows what happens when countries open to international trade. If for country H is indifferent to producing at any point along the production frontier. • At any price ratio p* that differs from the slope of the production frontier, a country will specialize completely. • If H will specialize in X at point H’. The reason is that Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  12. Y H C2 ● C1 ● ● Ah X H’ Specialization at alternative world price ratios Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  13. The production possibility frontier • Equilibrium with is given by , Y=O Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  14. Excess demand and international equilibrium • Results previously illustrated are transferred to an excess demand diagram. • The “flat” section of Country H’s excess demand curve at its autarky price ratio reflects the result discussed in the previous diagram: H will consume at Ah but will be indifferent to producing at any point on its production frontier • At world price ratios greater than autarky price ratio H will wish to export X. At world price ratios less than autarky price ratio H will wish to import X Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  15. p p = px / py ● ● ● ● C1 Eh C2 Ef Eh H’ 0 -(Xc –Xp) 0 H (Xc –Xp) -(Xc –Xp) Ef (Xc –Xp) Country H‘s excess demand curve International equilibrium Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  16. Excess demand and international equilibrium • The right side diagram in the previous figure shows the excess demand curve for both countries based on their production frontiers • International equilibrium occurs at price ratio p* at which the import demand of H matches the export supply of F. • The equilibrium world price ratio falls between the autarky price ratios of the two countries. In the case in which this circumstance does not occur, both countries would wish to export the same good • We know that when free trade price ratio is different from autarky price ratio for both countries, they attain mutual gains from trade. In the present model both countries must gain from trade although the distribution of the gains from trade could be uneven (the country with a larger distance between free trade price ratio and autarky price ratio gains more) Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  17. The role of wages • Until now, we have seen that in the Ricardian model comparative advantage is determined simply by differences in technology across countries. What is the role of wages in Ricardian model? • International differences induce adjustment of wages in order to reflect underlying real productivity differences. More productive economies will have higher real wages in equilibrium. However all workers gain real income in moving from autarky to free trade • The discussion about the role of wages in the model can start from the initial equilibrium in autarky. Because of perfect competition, we have: Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  18. The role of wages • From the previous profit maximization condition, it follows that the relative price in autarky is independent of the wage rate: • Given that the ratio between the marginal products in the two industries is equivalent to the ratio between input coefficients in the two industries, the previous expression reflects the Ricardian Labour Theory of Value • However, the wage rate is relevant for determining real wages of workers: • These “real wages” can be interpreted graphically as the end points on the budget line of an individual worker who owns 1 unit of labour Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  19. Y Slopep* ● ● Uf Ua X ● ● 0 Budget line of an individual worker in Country H Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  20. The role of wages • Now we consider the move from autarky to free trade. This movement induces an adjustment of nominal wages in both countries. • To determine the impact on real wages, note that H Country exports Y and F Country exports X. Therefore, in H country the real wage for a home worker is constant in terms of good Y because the competitive condition of production in industry Y requires that • Of course, the previous condition does not involve the good X because this good is not produced at home. This means that the real wage in terms of X changes because of the new price ratio determined by trade. Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  21. The role of wages • If H Country exports good Y, the international price ratio will be lower than the autarky price ratio and now the home worker can buy X at a lower price: • Given that the price ratio p* is the vertical intercept ( ) over the horizontal intercept, this last one has to be . • So the new real wage in terms of good X (the new horizontal intercept) increases in the presence of free trade: Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  22. The role of wages • So trade does not change the domestic real wage in terms of the good exported but alters the domestic real wage in terms of the good imported. Note in the previous figure that with the new budget line the utility of the domestic individual worker increases (same argument applies to the worker of the foreign Country, whose income is constant in terms of the good X but increases in terms of the good Y). • A final important point about the role of wages. It is probable that in free trade real wages are higher in one country in comparison with the other. Suppose that the home country has an absolute advantage in both industries. In such situation, for the good X we have and therefore: . • (same dimonstration applies to good Y). Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  23. The distribution of gains from trade: big versus small countries • One of the most important determinant of the distribution of the gains from trade among countries is the size of economies, measured in terms of either their factor endowments or their productivity levels • Suppose to make Country F bigger by shifting its production frontier farther out in a parallel way. This can be achieved either by increasing factor endowment or by increasing and • The following figure shows the expansion of production frontier from • to Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  24. Y C1 C0 X 0 Growth in Country F Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  25. The distribution of gains from trade: big versus small countries • The expansion of the production frontier will lead Country F to wish to trade more at any international price ratio. • In the next figure, we can observe the effect of the growth of the Country F in terms of the excess demand curve. The horizontal segment (equivalent to the distance ) expands indicating that the Country F now wishes to trade more at any price ratio. • But the equilibrium price ratio also changes and can no longer be an equilibrium price ratio: there is an excess supply of X, so the world price ratio must fall Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  26. ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● -(Xc –Xp) 0 (Xc –Xp) Expansion in Country F’s excess demand Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  27. The distribution of gains from trade: big versus small countries • The change of international price ratio has important implications in terms of the distribution of the gain from trade. • Country F gains less by growth than in the case of equilibrium at the initial world price ratio . In particular, F’s terms of trade have deteriorated, while H’s terms of trade have improved • The positive impact of F’s growth on H’s welfare due to a decline of international price ratio from to is shown in the following figure. Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  28. Y H C1 ● C0 ● X 0 H’ Effect of growth in country F on country H Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  29. The distribution of gains from trade: big versus small countries • The following figure shows an extreme case of uneven distribution of the gains from trade. Now Country F is so large in comparison with Country H that the equilibrium is reached at the autarky price ratio of Country F. In this case, all gains from trade are captured by Country H and Country F is indifferent to trade. • The discussion on the trade effects associated with the growth of country size leads to observe that smaller economies are the more probable gainer from free trade • Another point to remark is that the productivity growth of a country may be beneficial for the other (in the cases illustrated previously, H benefits from productivity growth of F in terms of a lower price of its import good) Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  30. p ● ● ● ● ● Ef 0 Eh -(Xc –Xp) (Xc –Xp) Equilibrium world price equal to Country F’s autarky price Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  31. Concluding remarks: key points • The slope of of a country’s production frontier reflects its relative abilities to produce X and Y. When the slope of production frontier differs between two countries a pattern of comparative advantage emerges. Actually, differences in the slope of PPF imply differences in the autarky price ratio and this creates the potential for gains from trade also in the case a country has an absolute advantage in both industries • Even if potential for gains from trade exists, it is not sure that these gains are captured in free trade. Another condition is required: the equilibrium free trade price ratio must lie between the autarky price ratios for the two countries. If this condition is satisfied, each country specializes according to its comparative advantage and gains from trade Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  32. Concluding remarks: key points • Individual workers in each country gains from trade in terms of an improvement of their living standards relative to autarky. However, real wages can be different in the two countries and the country with an absolute advantage necessarily has the higher real wages. So absolute advantage (in terms of productivity) is an important element of evaluation in international real wage comparison but is not relevant in terms of the direction of trade • The economic size is an important factor affecting the distribution of gains from trade. The economic size can be measured as the distance of PPF from the origin. When a country becomes bigger, its terms of trade tend to deteriorate and the equilibrium world price ratio tend to converge to the country’s autarky price ratio. This implies a transfer of gains from trade to the other country (because the distance between the word price ratio and the autarky price ratio of this country becomes maximum) Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

  33. Concluding remarks: key points • Therefore small country are likely to be the major gainers from free trade. That countries benefit from productivity growth in trading partners through the decline in prices of import goods Giuseppe Celi IEG 2007

More Related