280 likes | 439 Views
Perfectly Competitive Markets. Economics 110 Introduction to Economic Theory Professor Tanya Rosenblat. Experiment (Session 1). Widget Market (48 participants). Supply Schedule. Demand Schedule. Session 1: Supply and Demand for Widgets. 40 30 20 10. P R I C E.
E N D
Perfectly Competitive Markets Economics 110Introduction to Economic TheoryProfessor Tanya Rosenblat
Session 1: Supply and Demand for Widgets 40 30 20 10 P R I C E 8 16 24 Number of Bushels
Experimental Data • Round 1 – Average Price 18.3 (19.5)
Experimental Data • Round 2 – Average Price 17.4 (17.3)
A Demand Curve Can Be Thought of as a Schedule of Buyers’ Maximum Willingnesses to Pay Highest price at which individual is willing to buy Potential Buyer $ per unit • Only one buyer has a maximum willingness • to pay greater than $5.75 • Thus: at a price of $5.75, only one potential buyer (#1) • would buy. • Quantity demanded at $5.75 = 1 #1 $ 6.00 $6.50 #2 $ 5.50 #3 $ 5.00 $6.00 $5.75 #4 $ 4.50 $5.50 #5 $ 4.00 #6 $ 3.50 $5.00 #7 $ 3.00 $4.50 #8 $ 2.50 #9 $ 2.00 $4.00 #10 $ 1.50 $3.50 #11 $ 1.00 #12 $ 0.50 $3.00 $2.50 $2.25 • At a price of $2.25, eight potential buyers • would buy (#1 - #8). • Quantity demanded at $2.25 = 8. $2.00 $1.50 $1.00 Demand Curve $0.50 Quantity $- 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Notice that the demand curve also describes the maximum willingness to pay of all potential buyers in the market!
A Supply Curve Can Be Thought of as a Schedule of Seller’s Minimum Willingnesses to Sell Supply Curve • The price of $5.75 is greater than the • minimum willingness to sell for 11 potential sellers • Thus: quantity supplied at $5.75 = 11 $ per unit $6.50 $6.00 $5.75 Lowest price at which seller is willing to sell* $5.50 Potential Seller $5.00 #1 $ 0.50 $4.50 #2 $ 1.00 #3 $ 1.50 $4.00 #4 $ 2.00 $3.50 #5 $ 2.50 #6 $ 3.00 $3.00 #7 $ 3.50 $2.50 $2.25 #8 $ 4.00 #9 $ 4.50 $2.00 #10 $ 5.00 $1.50 #11 $ 5.50 #12 $ 6.00 $1.00 $0.50 Quantity $- 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Is There An Equilibrium in Our Market? Yes! Supply Curve $ per unit • At any price above $3.00 but below $3.50, exactly 6 potential buyers are willing to buy • At a price above $3.00 but below $3.50, exactly 6 potential sellers are willing to sell. • For any price in this band, quantity supplied equals quantity demanded at this price. $6.50 $6.00 $5.50 $5.00 $4.50 $4.00 $3.50 equilibrium price “band” $3.00 $2.50 $2.00 $1.50 $1.00 Demand Curve $0.50 Quantity $- 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
How Much Do Buyers Gain at the Market Equilibrium? Highest price at which individual is willing to buy Buyer #1: winning to pay as much as: $6.00 actually pays: $3.25 net gain (consumer surplus): $2.75 (area A) Potential Buyer $ per unit #1 $ 6.00 $6.50 #2 $ 5.50 Buyer #2: winning to pay as much as: $5.50 actually pays: $3.25 net gain (consumer surplus): $2.25 (area B) #3 $ 5.00 $6.00 A #4 $ 4.50 $5.50 #5 $ 4.00 B #6 $ 3.50 $5.00 Buyer #6: winning to pay as much as: $3.50 actually pays: $3.25 net gain (consumer surplus): $0.25 (area F) #7 $ 3.00 $4.50 #8 $ 2.50 #9 $ 2.00 $4.00 #10 $ 1.50 $3.50 #11 $ 1.00 F $3.25 #12 $ 0.50 $3.00 $2.50 $2.00 $1.50 These buyers do not buy Their consumer surplus is zero! $1.00 Demand Curve $0.50 Quantity $- 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Consumer Surplus • Consumer surplus: the aggregate net gain to consumers from purchasing at a given market price. • Equal to: the area underneath the demand curve above the market price • In our picture: consumer surplus at a market price of $3.25 equals area A+B+C+D+E+F. • This number, which equals $9.00, is the aggregate • difference between what consumers are willing to pay and what they actually pay. $ per unit $6.50 $6.00 A $5.50 B $5.00 C $4.50 D $4.00 E $3.50 F $3.25 $3.00 $2.50 $2.00 Consumer Surplus: Willingness to pay - Actual payment $1.50 $1.00 Demand Curve $0.50 Quantity $- 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
The Concept of Consumer Surplus Also Applies to “Smooth” Demand Curves P ($ per liter) • Consumers demand 4000 liters at $6 per unit. • Consumers surplus = difference between • total willingness to pay and • actual amount paid = area A • = $8,000. $10 A $6 MARKET DEMAND CURVE Q (liters per year) 4000
How Much Do Sellers Gain at the Market Equilibrium? Supply Curve $ per unit Seller #1: actually receives: $3.25 must receive at least: $0.50 net gain (producer surplus): $2.75 (area A) $6.50 $6.00 Lowest price at which seller is willing to sell* $5.50 Potential Seller Seller #2: actually receives: $3.25 must receive at least: $1.00 net gain (producer surplus): $2.25 (area B) $5.00 #1 $ 0.50 $4.50 #2 $ 1.00 #3 $ 1.50 $4.00 #4 $ 2.00 $3.50 #5 $ 2.50 $3.25 A B F #6 $ 3.00 $3.00 #7 $ 3.50 $2.50 #8 $ 4.00 Seller #6: actually receives: $3.25 must receive at least: $3.00 net gain (producer surplus): $0.25 (area F) #9 $ 4.50 $2.00 #10 $ 5.00 $1.50 #11 $ 5.50 #12 $ 6.00 $1.00 $0.50 Quantity $- 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Producer Surplus Supply Curve $ per unit Producer Surplus: Actual payment - required payment $6.50 $6.00 $5.50 $5.00 $4.50 $4.00 • Producer surplus: the aggregate net gain to sellers • from selling at a given market price. • Equal to: the area underneath the market price • above the supply curve. • In our picture: producer surplus at a market price of • $3.25 equals area A+B+C+D+E+F. • This number, which equals $9.00, is the aggregate • difference between what sellers actually receive • and the smallest amount they need to receive. $3.50 $3.25 A B C D E F $3.00 $2.50 $2.00 $1.50 $1.00 $0.50 Quantity $- 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Producer Surplus Also Applies to “Smooth” Supply Curves P ($ per liter) Market Supply Curve $6 A • Firms supply 4000 liters at $6 per liter. • Producer surplus is area A in the diagram = $8,000. $2 Q (liters per year) 4000
Total Economic Value Created in a Market = Consumer Surplus + Producer Surplus Supply Curve $ per unit $6.50 $6.00 $5.50 $5.00 $4.50 • Total economic value created when • market price is $3.25 • = Consumer surplus at $ 3.25 • + Producer surplus at $3.25 • = $9.00 + 9.00 • = $18.00 $4.00 $3.50 $3.25 $3.00 $2.50 $2.00 $1.50 $1.00 Demand Curve $0.50 Quantity $- 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
If The Market is Prevented From Reaching Equilibrium, Economic Surplus is Not Realized Supply Curve $ per unit $6.50 $6.00 $5.50 $5.00 • If, for some reason, potential buyers #3,4,5 • and potential sellers #3,4,5 were prevented • from participating in the market, • consumer and producer surplus would • be lost. • Gains from exchange would not be realized! • We say there is a deadweight loss: unrealized • economic benefits. • How could this happen? • Government interventions! $4.50 $4.00 $3.50 $3.00 $2.50 $2.00 $1.50 $1.00 Demand Curve $0.50 Quantity $- 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
The Economics of Price Controls Price ($ per unit) A S B D $2,000 E C $1,400 F D QD Q* QS E + D = Deadweight loss Quantity (units per period)
Elasticity • Where is the Demand Curve coming from? How do we measure its slope? • The Demand Curve tells us how much consumers will buy for different prices of the good • From Consumer Behavior, we know how to deduce from tastes how much an individual consumer will buy at a given price. Summing over consumers, we get the Demand Curve • The Demand Curve is (assumed to be) decreasing (The “Law of Demand”): The higher the price, the lower the consumption
How to measure elasticity? • It is important to measure how sensitive Demand is to changes in Prices • Preferably, this measure should not depend on units: are we counting in dollars, cents, or euros? Pounds, Kilograms or Tons? • The price elasticity of demand provides such a measure: In words, it is the % change in quantity for (or divided by) a given % change in prices (sometimes, the elasticity is defined as the opposite number: the precise convention does not matter, as long as one realizes that the law of demand applies)
The Importance of Elasticity • The Concept of Elasticity is used for other concepts: - Income elasticity of Demand: - Price Elasticity of Supply: • What affects the Slope? When is it steep? It is steep when there is no good substitute
Examples • Linear Demand • Q = a – bP • Elasticity =
Elasticity • Elastic – responsive to price changes • Inelastic – not responsive to price changes Examples: - An unconscious bleeding man is brought to the hospital emergency room. - Among hospital patients whose insurance will pay all charges, what would the demand be like for nurse-administered propoxyphene (Darvon), a pain-killer? - Now suppose that the patients are in managed care plans that pressure physicians to use lower-price drugs. What might demand for the Darvon be? - A patient is given a presciption for a drug to control high blood pressure. The patient's insurance doesn't cover drugs, so the patient must pay out of pocket.
Elasticity • Demand is more elastic if the decision-maker has an incentive to save money and if there is an adequate substitute for the product or service.
What Shifts Demand Curves? • Change in income • Change in a price of a substitute • Change in a price of a complement • Change in composition of population • Change in tastes • Change in information • Change in availability of credit • Change in expectations
What Shifts Supply Curve? • Change in price of inputs • Change in technology • Change in natural environment • Change in availability of credit • Change in expectations