420 likes | 652 Views
Chapter 3: DECISION ANALYSIS. Part 2. (Probability)(Payoff). Over States of Nature. Decision Making Under Risk. Probabilistic decision situation States of nature have probabilities of occurrence.
E N D
Chapter 3:DECISION ANALYSIS Part 2
(Probability)(Payoff) Over States of Nature Decision Making Under Risk • Probabilistic decision situation • States of nature have probabilities of occurrence. • The probability estimate for the occurrence of each state of nature( if available) can be incorporated in the search for the optimal decision. • For each decision calculate its expected payoff by • Expected Payoff =S
Decision Making Under Risk (cont.) • Select the decision with the best expected payoff
The Optimal decision TOM BROWN - continued (0.2)(250) + (0.3)(200) + (0.3)(150) + (0.1)(-100) + (0.1)(-150) = 130
Decision Making Criteria (cont.) • When to Use the Expected Value Approach • The Expected Value Criterion is useful in cases where long run planning is appropriate, and decision situations repeat themselves. • One problem with this criterion is that it does not consider attitude toward possible losses.
Expected Value of Perfect Information • The gain in Expected Return obtained from knowing with certainty the future state of nature is called: Expected Value of Perfect Information (EVPI) • It is also the Smallest Expect Regret of any decision alternative. Therefore, the EVPI is the expected regret corresponding to the decision selected using the expected value criterion
Expected Value of Perfect Information (cont.) • EVPI = ERPI - EREV • EREV: Expected Return of the EV criterion . • Expected Return with Perfect Information ERPI= (best outcome of 1st state of nature)*(Probability of 1st state of nature) + ….. +(best outcome of last state of nature)*(Probability of last state of nature)
Stock TOM BROWN - continued If it were known with certainty that there will be a “Large Rise” in the market -100 250 500 60 Large rise Similarly, ... the optimal decision would be to invest in... Expected Return with Perfect information = 0.2(500)+0.3(250)+0.3(200)+0.1(300)+0.1(60) = $271 EVPI = ERPI - EV = $271 - $130 = $141
Expected Value of Perfect Information (cont.) • Another way to determine EVPI as follows If Tom knows the market will show a large rise, he should buy the “stock”, within profit $500, or a gain of $250 over what he would earn from the “bond” (optimal decision without the additional information).
Expected Value of Perfect Information (cont.) EVPI= 0.2(250) + 0.3(50) +0.3(50)+ 0.1(400)+ 0.1(210)= 141
Baysian Analysis - Decision Making with Imperfect Information • Baysian Statistic play a role in assessing additional information obtained from various sources. • This additional information may assist in refining original probability estimates, and help improve decision making.
When the stock market showed a large rise the forecast was “positive growth” 80% of the time. TOM BROWN - continued • Tom can purchase econometric forecast results for $50. • The forecast predicts “negative” or “positive” econometric growth. • Statistics regarding the forecast.
TOM BROWN - continued • P(forecast predicts “positive” | small rise in market) = 0.7 • P(forecast predicts “ negative” | small rise in market) = 0.3 Should Tom purchase the Forecast ?
SOLUTION • Tom should determine his optimal decisions when the forecast is “positive” and “negative”. • If his decisions change because of the forecast, he should compare the expected payoff with and without the forecast. • If the expected gain resulting from the decisions made with the forecast exceeds $50, he should purchase the forecast.
SOLUTION • To find Expected payoff with forecast Tom should determine what to do when: • The forecast is “positive growth” • The forecast is “negative growth”
SOLUTION • Tom needs to know the following probabilities • P(Large rise | The forecast predicted “Positive”) • P(Small rise | The forecast predicted “Positive”) • P(No change | The forecast predicted “Positive ”) • P(Small fall | The forecast predicted “Positive”) • P(Large Fall | The forecast predicted “Positive”)
SOLUTION • P(Large rise | The forecast predicted “Negative ”) • P(Small rise | The forecast predicted “Negative”) • P(No change | The forecast predicted “Negative”) • P(Small fall | The forecast predicted “Negative”) • P(Large Fall) | The forecast predicted “Negative”) Bayes’ Theorem provides a procedure to calculate these probabilities
Bayes’ Theorem • P(A|B) = • Proof: p(A|B)= P (A and B) / P(B) (1) P(B|A)= P(A and B)/P(A) P(A and B) = P(B|A)*P(A) (1) P(A|B)=P(B|A)*P(A)/P(B)
Bayes’ Theorem (cont.) • Often we begin probability analysis with initial or prior probabilities. • Then, from a sample , special report, or product test we obtain some additional information. • Given this information, we calculate revised or posterior probability. Prior probabilities New information Posterior probabilities
P(B |A i)P(A i) [ P(B | A 1)P(A 1)+ P(B | A 2)P(A 2)+…+ P(B | A n)P(A n) ] P(A i| B) = Bayes’ Theorem(cont.) Posterior probabilities Probabilities determined after the additional info becomes available Prior probabilities Probabilities estimated Determined based on Current info, before New info becomes available
The tabular approach to calculating posterior probabilities for positive economical forecast X Ai: large rise B: forecast positive P(Bi |Ai )P(Ai) P(forecast= Positive| large rise)P( large rise)
= X 0.16/ 0.56 The probability that the stock market shows “Large Rise” given that the forecast predicted “Positive” The Probability that the forecast is “positive” and the stock market shows “Large Rise”. Probability( forecast= positive) = 0.16+ 0.21+0.15+ 0.04+ 0.0 = 0.56
= X • The tabular approach to calculating posterior probabilities for “negative” ecnomical forecast • Probability (forecast= negative) = 0.44
WINQSB printout for the calculation of the Posterior probabilities
Gold Gold Expected Value of Sample Information EVSI • gain from making decisions based on Sample Information. • With the forecast available, the Expected Value of Return is revised. • Calculate Revised Expected Values for a given forecast as follows. EV(Invest in……. |“Positive” forecast) = =.286( )+.375( )+.268( )+.071( )+0( ) = EV(Invest in ……. | “Negative” forecast) = =.091( )+.205( )+.341( )+.136( )+.227( ) = Bond -100 100 200 300 0 $180 $84 250 -100 100 200 150 200 -100 300 0 -150 -100 100 200 300 0 Bond 0 -100 100 200 300 $120 $ 65 250 -100 100 200 150 200 -100 300 -150 0
EREV = Expected Value Without Sampling Information = 130 Expected Value of Sample Information - Excel • The rest of the revised EV s are calculated in a similar manner. Invest in Stock when the Forecast is “Positive” ERSI = Expected Return with sample Information = (0.56)(250) + (0.44)(120) = $193 Invest in Gold when the forecast is “Negative” So, Should Tom purchase the Forecast ?
EVSI = Expected Value of Sampling Information = ERSI - EREV = 193 - 130 = $63. Yes, Tom should purchase the Forecast. His expected return is greater than the Forecast cost. • Efficiency = EVSI / EVPI = 63 / 141 = 0.45
Game Theory • Game theory can be used to determine optimal decision in face of other decision making players. • All the players are seeking to maximize their return. • The payoff is based on the actions taken by all the decision making players.
Game Theory (cont.) • Classification of Games • Number of Players • Two players - Chess • Multiplayer - More than two competitors (Poker) • Total return • Zero Sum - The amount won and amount lost by all competitors are equal (Poker among friends) • Nonzero Sum -The amount won and the amount lost by all competitors are not equal (Poker In A Casino)
Game Theory (cont.) • Sequence of Moves • Sequential - Each player gets a play in a given sequence. • Simultaneous - All players play simultaneously.