1 / 22

Chapter 5

Chapter 5. THE IMPORTANCE OF SCALE AND TIMING IN PROJECT APPRAISAL. Why is scale important?. Too large or too small can destroy a good project

julian-best
Download Presentation

Chapter 5

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Chapter 5 THE IMPORTANCE OF SCALE AND TIMING IN PROJECT APPRAISAL

  2. Why is scale important? • Too large or too small can destroy a good project • One of the most important decision that a project analyst is to make is the "scale" of the investment. This is mostly thought as a technical issue but it has a financial and economic dimension as well. • Right scale should be chosen to maximize NPV. • In evaluating a project to determine its best scale, the most important principle is to treat each incremental change in its size as a project in itself

  3. Why is scale important? (Cont’d) • By comparing the present value of the incremental benefits with the present value of the incremental costs, scale is increased until NPV of the incremental net benefits is negative. (incremental NPV is called Marginal Net Present Value (MNPV) • We must first make sure that the NPV of the overall project is positive. Secondly, the net present value of the last addition must also be greater than or equal to zero.

  4. Bt - Ct B3 B2 B1 0 Time C1 C2 C3 Choice of Scale • Rule: Optimal scale is when NPV = 0 for the last addition to scale and NPV > 0 for the whole project • Net benefit profiles for alternative scales of a facility NPV (B1 – C1) 0 ? NPV (B2 – C2) 0 ? NPV (B3 – C3) 0 ?

  5. NPV (+) NPV of Project 0 Scale of Project A B C D E F G H I J K L M N (-) Determination of Scale of Project • Relationship between net present value and scale

  6. Internal Rate of Return (IRR) Criterion • The optimal scale of a project can also be determined by the use of the IRR. Here it is assumed that each successive increment of investment has a unique IRR. • Incremental investment is made as long as the MIRR is above or equal to the discount rate.

  7. Table 5-1 Determination of Optimum Scale of Irrigation Dam (Cont’d) Year Scale 0 1 2 3 4 5 -  Costs Benefits NPV 10% IRR S0 S1 S2 S3 S4 S5 S6 -3000 -4000 -5000 -6000 -7000 -8000 -9000 50 125 400 800 1000 1101 1150 50 125 400 800 1000 1101 1150 50 125 400 800 1000 1101 1150 50 125 400 800 1000 1101 1150 50 125 400 800 1000 1101 1150 -2500 -2750 -1000 2000 3000 3010 2500 0.017 0.031 0.080 0.133 0.143 0.138 0.128 Opportunity cost of funds (discount rate) = 10%

  8. Table 5-1 Determination of Optimum Scale of Irrigation Dam Year Scale 0 1 2 3 4 5 -  Costs Benefits NPV 10% IRR S0 S1 S2 S3 S4 S5 S6 -3000 -4000 -5000 -6000 -7000 -8000 -9000 50 125 400 800 1000 1101 1150 50 125 400 800 1000 1101 1150 50 125 400 800 1000 1101 1150 50 125 400 800 1000 1101 1150 50 125 400 800 1000 1101 1150 -2500 -2750 -1000 2000 3000 3010 2500 0.017 0.031 0.080 0.133 0.143 0.138 0.128 Opportunity cost of funds (discount rate) = 10%

  9. Note: • NPV of last increment to scale 0 at scale S5. i.e. NPV of scale 5 = 10. • NPV of project is maximized at scale of 5, i.e. NPV1-5 = 3010. • IRR is maximized at scale 4. • When the IRR on the last increment to scale (MIRR) is equal to discount rate the NPV of project is maximized.

  10. Percent Maximum MIRR Maximum IRR (0.14) IRR>r MIRR>r Discount Rate (r) Opp. Cost of Funds (0.10) MIRR<r Sn S4 Scale S3 S5 Figure 5-3 Relationship between MIRR, IRR and DR • at Scale 3: Maximum point of MIRR (0.40) between Scale 3 and Scale 4: MIRR is greater than IRR; MIRR and IRR are greater than r • at Scale 4: Maximum point of IRR (0.143) and MIRR intersects with IRR between Scale 4 and Scale 5: MIRR is smaller than IRR; MIRR and IRR are greater than r • at Scale 5: MIRR is equal to Discount Rate between Scale 5 and Scale N: MIRR is smaller than IRR; MIRR is smaller than r; IRR is greater than r • at some Scale N: IRR is equal to Discount Rate 

  11. Figure 5-4 Relationship between MNPV and NPV • at Scale 3: Maximum point of MNPV ($3000) at 0.10 Discount rate • at Scale 4: Maximum point of NPV (zero) at 0.14 Discount Rate between Scale 0 and Scale 5: NPV is positive and NPV it increases • at Scale 5: Maximum point of NPV and MNPV is equal to zero between Scale 5 and Scale N: NPV is positive and it decreases • at some Scale N: NPV is equal to zero • after Scale N: NPV is negative and it decreases NPV (+)  Maximum NPV $3010 $3000 Maximum MNPV NPV(0.10) Percent S5  Scale Sn S3 S4 0 NPV(0.14) NPV (-) MNPV (0.10) NPV(0.10) 0 

  12. Figure 5-5 Relationship between MIRR, IRR, MNPV and NPV   

  13. Relationship between MIRR, IRR, MNPV and NPV • When MNPV is positive – NPV is increasing • When MNPV is zero – NPV is at the maximum and MIRR is equal to Discount Rate • When NPV is zero – IRR is equal to Discount Rate • When MIRR is greater than IRR – IRR is increasing • When MIRR is equal to IRR – IRR is at the maximum • When MIRR is smaller than IRR – IRR is decreasing • IRR is greater than Discount Rate as long as NPV is positive • MIRR is greater than Discount Rate as long as NPV is increasing

  14. Relationship between MIRR, IRR and NPV (cont’d.) • Figure 5.5 gives the relationship between MIRR, IRR and NPV. • MIRR cuts IRR from above at its maximum point. • Scale of the project must be increased until MIRR is just equal to the discount rate. This is the optimal scale (S5). • At the optimum scale NPV is maximum and MIRR is equal to the discount rate (10%). • When NPV is equal to zero, IRR is equal to the discount rate (10%). • To illustrate the procedure, construction of an irrigation dam which could be built at different heights is given as an example in Table 5.1.

  15. Timing of Investments Key Questions: 1.What is right time to start a project? 2.What is right time to end a project? Four Illustrative Cases of Project Timing Case 1. Benefits (net of operating costs) increasing continuously with calendar time. Investments costs are independent of calendar time Case 2. Benefits (net of operating costs) increasing with calendar time. Investment costs function of calendar time Case 3. Benefits (net of operating costs) rise and fall with calendar time. Investment costs are independent of calendar time Case 4. Costs and benefits do not change systematically with calendar time

  16. Benefits and Costs B (t) I D E rK A C B1 Time t0 t1 t2 rKt Bt+1 <> K rKt > Bt+1 Postpone rKt < Bt+1 Start K Case 1: Timing of Projects:When Potential Benefits Are a Continuously Rising Function of Calendar Time but Are Independent of Time of Starting Project

  17. Timing for Start of Operation of Roojport Dam, South Africa of Marginal Economic Unit Water Cost 6.00 5.52 5.00 4.00 4.09 3.25 3.00 2.00 2.19 Economic Water Cost Rand/m3 1.98 1.80 1.65 1.52 1.41 1.31 1.22 1.00 1.14 1.07 1.03 1.03 0.00 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 Numbers of Years Postponed

  18. Benefits and Costs B (t) D E rK0 A C B1 B2 0 Time t1 t2 t3 K0 K1 rKt >Bt+1+ (Kt+1-Kt) Postpone rKt < Bt+1 + (Kt+1-Kt) Start K0 F G K1 I H Case 2: Timing of Projects: When Both Potential Benefits and Investments AreA Function of Calendar Time

  19. Benefits and Costs SV B C rK I A rSV B (t) 0 Time t0 t1 tn tn+1 t* Start if: rKt* < Bt*+1 Stop if: rSVt - B(tn+1) - ΔSVt > 0 ; SVt = SVt -SVt n n n+1 n+1 n+1 SVt SVt tn tn Bi Bi > 0 n n t*r Do project if: NPV = ∑ - Kt* + (1+r)t - t* (1+r)t - t* (1+r)i-t* (1+r)i-t* n n K0 K1 K2 i=t*+1 i=t*+1 K <0 t*r Do not do project if: NPV = ∑ - Kt* + Case 3: Timing of Projects: When Potential Benefits Rise and Decline According to Calendar Time

  20. The Decision Rule If (rSVt - Bt - ΔSVt ) > 0 Stop (ΔSVt = SVt - SVt ) < 0 Continue This rule has 5 special cases: 1. SV > 0 and ΔSV < 0, e.g. Machinery 2. SV > 0 but ΔSV > 0, e.g. Land 3. SV < 0, but ΔSV = 0, e.g. A nuclear plant 4. SV < 0, but ΔSV > 0, e.g. Severance pay for workers 5. SV < 0 and ΔSV < 0 e.g. Clean-up costs

  21. Benefits and Costs D Benefits From K1 C B A Benefits From K0 0 t0 t1 t2 tn tn+1 K0 K1 K0 K1 Timing of Projects:When The Patterns of Both Potential Benefits and CostsDepend on Time of Starting Project

More Related