1 / 20

Hidden Information Problem in Microeconomics

This exercise illustrates and solves the hidden information problem in microeconomics. It explores the concept of full-information solutions, incentive-compatibility problems, and finding second-best solutions.

Download Presentation

Hidden Information Problem in Microeconomics

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Exercise 11.1 MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell March 2007

  2. Ex 11.1(1): Question • purpose: to illustrate and solve the “hidden information” problem • method: find full information solution, describe incentive-compatibility problem, then find second-best solution

  3. Ex 11.1(1): Budget constraint • Consumer has income y and faces two possibilities • “not buy”: all y spent on other goods • “buy”: y F(q) spent on other goods • Define a binary variable i: • i = 0 represents the case “not buy” • i = 1 represents the case “buy” • Then the budget constraint can be written • x + iF(q) ≤ y

  4. Ex 11.1(2): Question method: • First draw ICs in space of quality and other goods • Then redraw in space of quality and fee • Introduce iso-profit curves • Full-information solutions from tangencies

  5. F ta tb q quality Ex 11.1(2): Preferences: quality • (quality, other-goods) space x • high-taste type • low-taste type • redraw in (quality, fee) space ta tb preference • IC must be linear in t • ta > tb • Because linear ICs can only intersect once q quality

  6. F q quality Ex 11.1(2): Isoprofit curves, quality • (quality, fee) space • Iso-profit curve: low profits • lso-profit curve: medium profits • lso-profit curve: high profits increasing profit P2 = F2  C(q) • Increasing, convex in quality P1 = F1 C(q) P0 = F0 C(q)

  7. Ex 11.1(2): Full-information solution • reservation IC, high type F • Firm’s feasible set for a high type • Reservation IC + feasible set, low type • lso-profit curves taq • Full-information solution, high type • Full-information solution, low type • F*a tbq • Type-a participation constraint taqa Fa≥0 • F*b • Type-b participation constraint tbqb Fb≥0 • Full information so firm can put each type on reservation IC q q*b q*a quality

  8. Ex 11.1(3,4): Question method: • Set out nature of the problem • Describe in full the constraints • Show which constraints are redundant • Solve the second-best problem

  9. Ex 11.1(3,4): Misrepresentation? • Feasible set, high type F • Feasible set, low type • Full-information solution • Type-a consumer with a type-b deal taq • preference F*a • Type-a participation constraint taqa Fa≥0 tbq • Type-b participation constraint tbqb Fb≥0 • F*b • A high type-consumer would strictly prefer the contract offered to a low type q q*b q*a quality

  10. Ex 11.1(3,4): background to problem • Utility obtained by each type in full-information solution is y • each person is on reservation utility level • given the U function, if you don’t consume the good you get exactly y • If a-type person could get a b-type contract • a-type’s utility would then be • taq*b F*b+y • given that tbq*b F*b= 0… • …a-type’s utility would be [ta tb]q*b + y >y • So an a-type person would want to take a b-type contract • In deriving second-best contracts take account of • participation constraints • this incentive-compatibility problem

  11. Ex 11.1(3,4): second-best problem • Participation constraint for the two types • taqa Fa ≥ 0 • tbqb Fb ≥ 0 • Incentive compatibility requires that, for the two types: • taqa Fa≥ taqb Fb • tbqb Fb≥ tbqa Fa • Suppose there is a proportion p, 1 p of a-types and b-types • Firm's problem is to choose qa, qb, Fa and Fb to max expected profits • p[Fa C(qa)] + [1 p][Fb C(qb)] subject to • the participation constraints • the incentive-compatibility constraints • However, we can simplify the problem • which constraints are slack? • which are binding?

  12. Ex 11.1(3,4): participation, b-types • First, we must have taqa Fa ≥ tbqb Fb • this is because • taqa Fa≥ taqb Fb (a-type incentive compatibility) and • ta > tb (a-type has higher taste than b-type) • This implies the following: • if tbqb Fb > 0 (b-type participation slack) • then also taqa Fa > 0 (a-type participation slack) • But these two things cannot be true at the optimum • if so it would be possible for firm to increase both Fa and Fb • thus could increase profits • So b-type participation constraint must be binding • tbqb Fb = 0

  13. Ex 11.1(3,4): participation, a-types • If Fb > 0 at the optimum, then qb > 0 • follows from binding b-type participation constraint • tbqb Fb = 0 • This implies taqb Fb > 0 • because a-type has higher taste than b-type • ta > tb • This in turn implies taqa Fa > 0 • follows from a-type incentive-compatibility constraint • taqa Fa ≥ taqb Fb • So a-type participation constraint is slack and can be ignored

  14. Ex 11.1(3,4): incentive compatibility, a-types • Could a-type incentive-compatibility constraint be slack? • could we have taqa Fa > taqb Fb ? • If so then it would be possible to increase Fa … • …without violating the constraint • this follows because a-type participation constraint is slack • taqa Fa > 0 • So a-type incentive-compatibility must be binding • taqa Fa = taqb Fb

  15. Ex 11.1(3,4): incentive compatibility, b-types • Could b-type incentive-compatibility constraint be binding? • tbqa Fa = tbqb Fb ? • If so, then qa= qb • follows from fact that a-type incentive-compatibility constraint is binding • taqa Fa = taqb Fb • which, with the above, would imply [tb ta]qa= [tb ta]qb • given that ta > tb this can only be true if qa= qb • So, both incentive-compatibility conditions bind only with “pooling” • but firm can do better than pooling solution: • increase profits by forcing high types to reveal themselves • So the b-type incentive-compatibility constraint must be slack • tbqb Fb > taqb Fb • …and it can be ignored

  16. Ex 11.1(3,4): Lagrangean • Firm's problem is therefore • max expected profits subject to.. • …binding participation constraint of b type • …binding incentive-compatibility constraint of a type • Formally, choose qa, qb, Fa and Fb to max • p[Fa C(qa)] + [1 p][Fb C(qb)] • + l[tbqb Fb] • + m[taqa Fa  taqb+Fb] • Lagrange multipliers are • l for the b-type participation constraint • m for the a-type incentive compatibility constraint

  17. Ex 11.1(3,4): FOCs • Differentiate Lagrangean with respect to Fa and set result to zero: • p m = 0 • which implies m = p • Differentiate Lagrangean with respect to qa and set result to zero: • pCq(qa) + mta = 0 • given the value of m this implies Cq(qa) = ta • But this condition means, for the high-value a types: • marginal cost of quality = marginal value of quality • the “no-distortion-at-the-top” principle

  18. Ex 11.1(3,4): FOCs (more) • Differentiate Lagrangean with respect to Fa and set result to zero: • 1p l + m = 0 • given the value of m this implies l = 1 • Differentiate Lagrangean with respect to qb and set result to zero: • [1p]Cq(qb) + ltbmta = 0 • given the values of l and m this implies Cq(qa) = ta • [1p]Cq(qb) + tbpta = 0 • Rearranging we find for the low-value b-types • marginal cost of quality < marginal value of quality

  19. F q quality Ex 11.1(3,4): Second-best solution • Feasible set for each type • Iso-profit contours • Contract for low type • Contract for high type taq preference • • Low type is on reservation IC, but MRS≠MRT Fa tbq • High type is on IC above reservation level, but MRS=MRT • Fb qb q*a

  20. Ex 11.1: Points to remember • Full-information solution is bound to be exploitative • Be careful to specify which constraints are important in the second-best • Interpret the FOCs carefully

More Related