1 / 27

Development Targets and Costs

Development Targets and Costs. Based on paper by Luc Christiaensen Christopher Scott Quentin Wodon. Outline . Current practice The political economy of target setting Approaches to target setting Historical benchmarking; Macro-simulations; Micro-simulations

Download Presentation

Development Targets and Costs

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Development Targets and Costs Based on paper by Luc Christiaensen Christopher Scott Quentin Wodon

  2. Outline • Current practice • The political economy of target setting • Approaches to target setting Historical benchmarking; Macro-simulations; Micro-simulations • Approaches to cost estimation Average costs and efficiency • Concluding remarks

  3. 1. Are current targets realistic? • A target is a value which a specific indicator should attain by a particular date • Current practice • Honduras: cost of reaching PRSP targets and IDG goals together with anticipated wage increase for public employees is high vs HIPC debt relief • Guinea: • Goal: 10 % annual agricultural growth rate by 2010; • Only 5 % of the 3921 recorded 3-year moving averages of ag growth in all countries worldwide over past 4 decades exceeded 10 % growth rate • Cambodia: • Goal: reduce child undernutrition by 15 % points from 1998 to 2000; • requires annual GDP/cap growth rate of 31 % (2005 as end date)

  4. 2. Political economy of target setting • Targets provide incentives a) Resource mobilization • targets must be realistic b) Resource allocation and consensus building  broad societal support and iterative process required  proliferation of targets erodes their effectiveness

  5. Political economy of target setting, cont. 2 c) Performance evaluation: targets introduce accountability • Targets must be attainable and carry broad societal support • Poor performance by implementing actors must be distinguishable from the effects of external shocks • Failure to meet targets must entail consequences for the actors While targets have in principle positive incentive effects, these do not follow automatically

  6. Political economy of target setting, cont. 3 • Experience from Britain • When the Government set local authorities a target for collecting recyclable waste, it seemed a good idea. Even better, the local authorities persuaded residents to take the trouble to separate the stuff that was worth recycling from all the rest--and met their target. There was only one snag. The target was for collecting recyclable waste, not for recycling it. As a result, some local authorities put the rubbish that had been so carefully separated back in with the rest of their garbage, and incinerated the lot. Targets must be SMART: Specific, Measurable, Achievable, Relevant and Time-bound

  7. Selected choices in target setting • Targets for inputs, outputs, or for outcomes and impacts? • Focus on outcome and impact targets, though input and output targets possible for short run • Check for vertical and horizontal consistency (Uganda) • Caution against proliferation of targets • Point targets or target ranges? • Given uncertainty surrounding input/output relations: • target ranges for outcomes/impacts • target points for inputs/outputs

  8. Selected choices in target setting, cont. 2 • Aggregate or disaggregate targets? • Equity versus efficiency • But: perverse incentives and proliferation of targets • Short-run or long-run targets? • Decision rule: marginal cost of, say, poverty reduction equated across time periods • In practice: thought needs to be given to appropriate time path for achieving the target, depending on state of country

  9. 3. Approaches to target setting • To facilitate resource allocation and to foster accountability it is key that targets are realistic: they must be technically and fiscally attainable • Three methods to gauge technical feasibility • Historical benchmarking • Macro-simulations • Micro-simulations

  10. 3.1 Historical benchmarking • Historical evidence and international comparison • Neither time nor skill intensive and data readily available hence, this is a minimum requirement • Agricultural growth in Guinea and neighboring countries 1970-2000

  11. 3.2 Macro-simulations • Gauge feasibility of poverty and social development targets by feasibility of implicit economic growth requirements • Two methods to set targets for poverty • Growth required to reduce poverty by a certain percentage, assuming no change in income distribution • Estimated net elasticity to growth

  12. Liberia: growth & pov. simulations

  13. Macro-simulations, continued • Estimated elasticity of social indicators to GDP/cap growth controlling for time trends and urbanization ; (elasticities can be estimated with world wide panel data (splines, 5 intervals) for GDP/cap and urbanization) • Exemples: • Demery and Walton (1999) use an elasticity of under 5 child mortality to GDP/cap growth of –0.4 (SimSIP elasticity varies between zero and –0.47) • Alderman et al. (2000) estimate an elasticity of prevalence of child malnutrition to GDP/cap growth of - 0.09 (SimSIP elasticity between zero and –1.1)

  14. Macro-simulations, continued • Other intervening factors may be important  results of growth based simulations indicative only • Some tools arguably more sophisticated though also more data and skill intensive; yet literature now exists • Must be used with caution as results are not indicative of policy actions needed

  15. 3.3 Micro-simulations • Country-specific nature of relationship between development outcomes and their determinants lost in macro approach  regression analysis and micro-simulations based on household data • Application to child malnutrition in Ethiopia: • 15 years of 2.5 % growth of income/adult equivalent and bringing at least one female adult/household up to level of primary school level reduce prevalence of child stunting by 9 to 29 percent, far removed from international goal of halving child stunting by 2015 • If combined with nutrition education programs  reduction by up to 42 % • Increasingly possible, as more and more household data sets are becoming available, yet technically difficult

  16. 4. The cost of reaching a target • Targets must be technically AND fiscally attainable • Effect of (public and private) expenditures on development outcomes depends on: • amount spent on these objectives • effectiveness of money spent • Fiscal sustainability of targets can be gauged by • Government’s capacity for increasing public spending • Government’s scope for enhancing efficiency of its spending

  17. 4.1 Costs and fiscal sustainability • Need for detailed sectoral information • SimSIP simulator for estimating costs of reaching education targets • Education example: average costing method • Need for assumptions on: • Demographics: number of children of various age groups joining education system

  18. Costs and fiscal sustainability, cont.2 Data on • Cost parameters: • Supply-side costs: teacher wage, teacher-student ratio, administrative costs • Demand side costs: stipend value, coverage • Investment costs: cost per classroom, teacher training • Delivery system: • length of schooling cycle, repetition, promotion, and drop out rates by cycle or by grade, distribution of age at entry for each cycle Targets for • Changes in distribution of age at entry • Changes in repetition, promotion and drop out rates

  19. Costs and fiscal sustainability, cont.3 • Logic of education costing • Detailed cohort analysis depending on efficiency parameters (promotion, repetition, drop out, …) • Parametrize software to reproduce initial conditions • budget spending by cyle • teacher salaries, share of administrative budget • number of children enrolled by cycle • net & gross enrollment rates, with targets • realistic other parameters (cost of new schools/classrooms) • Change efficiency parameters and demographics over time, and track various costs as they evolve • Number students  number teachers/classrooms  costs

  20. Costs and fiscal sustainability, cont.3 • Selected parameters for Liberia – primary level (all parameters must be checked) • Net enrollment (CWIQ 2007): 37.3% (low probably due to conflict – older children enrolling in last few years) • Gross enrollment (CWIQ 2007): 86.3% • Budget: +/- US$ 4 million • Number of teachers: 26,755  cost/teacher • Number of students: 894,316  pupil/teacher ratio 33 • Share of public sector: 67% (incl. community) • New entrants every year: +/-110,000, to increase in future • Admin cost: 15% (assumption)

  21. Costs and fiscal sustainability, cont.3 • Selected parameters for Liberia – secondary level (all parameters must be checked) • Net enrollment (CWIQ 2007): 15.2% (low probably due to conflict – older children enrolling in last few years) • Gross enrollment (CWIQ 2007): 51.3% • Budget: +/- US$ 1.5 million (need to check) • Number of teachers: 8756  cost/teacher • Number of students: 150,914  pupil/teacher ratio 17 • Share of public sector: 46% (incl. community) • New entrants: depends on primary schooling parameters • Admin costs: 15% (assumption)

  22. Example of simulation (VERY prelim.) Note: 2003 in simulator represents 2006 in reality; Assumes no increases in real wage for teachers; Secondary spending expected to increase faster; Possibility to estimate needed investment costs; overall costs probably underestimated/need to get correct data

  23. 4.2 Efficiency considerations • Outcomes can be increased through • Expansion of inputs keeping efficiency constant • Increase in efficiency keeping inputs constant • Given limited tax base, room for expansion of social expenditures often narrow • Murray et al. (1994): typical country in Sub Saharan Africa could improve health outcomes by 40 % simply by reallocating resources to most cost-effective intervention mix

  24. Measuring efficiency Best performance frontier b E=a/(a+b) o a

  25. Measuring efficiency, examples • Efficiency of national health systems (WHO) • Output: disability adjusted life expectancy Inputs: real total (private and public) health expenditures/capita and average years of schooling • E>0.7 (good): Costa Rica, Sri Lanka, Bangladesh (good) 0.7<E<0.5 (mediocre): Gambia, Viet Nam E<0.5 (poor): most African countries, e.g. E for Guinea and Kenya respectively 0.47 and 0.32

  26. Concluding remarks & discussion points • In principle, targets powerful tools to foster accountability and facilitate consensus building; • Targets must be carefully designed and evaluated; they must be SMART • Chapter focused on feasibility aspect, though also need for more hard rules on other aspects of target design

  27. Remarks & discussion points, cont. 2 • Set of readily applicable tools to assess technical and fiscal feasibility of development targets • Each tool has its limitation  need for joint application • Tools must be used with care; they are indicative of feasibility of targets, but not of policies needed • Tools only useful in practice if readily available • Need for continuous updating of elasticities = public good • Encourage policy simulations based on household data • Research on efficiency of expenditures on social outcomes

More Related