160 likes | 223 Views
Explore the trade-offs and complementarities between fiscal discipline and structural reforms in the context of the Stability and Growth Pact and Lisbon Agenda. This paper aims to reconcile opposite views on these policies through a simple model and empirical evidence.
E N D
Is Lisbon far from Maastricht?Trade-offs and Complementarities between Fiscal Discipline and Structural Reforms Marco Buti, Werner Roeger, and Alessandro Turrini Fiscal Policy Challenges in Europe Berlin, 22-23 March 2007
The issue • Fiscal discipline to ensure macroeconomic stability in EMU → Stability and Growth Pact Structural reforms to raise growth potential and enhance adjustment to stocks → Lisbon agenda • Two opposite views: • “Brussels-Frankfurt (-Washington) consensus”: do both at the same time • “Either or view”: if you do one, you cannot do the other • Can the above views be reconciled in a unified framework for analysis? Can we find the conditions under which Maastricht and Lisbon are complements and those under which they are substitutes? • Aim of the paper: • Develop a simple model • Provide empirical evidence
The LiteratureTheoretical arguments • “Brussels – Frankfurt consensus” (Sapir et al. 2004) • Direct budgetary gains of reforms • Back against the wall/ “TINA” (e.g., Bean (1998), Calmfors (2001)) • Fiscal restrictions as signalling device (e.g., Deroose and Turrini (2005)) • “Either/or view”: • Budgetary losses of reforms: direct or indirect, to compensate reform losers (e.g., Razin-Sadka (2002), Beetsma and Debrun (2004)) • Expansionary policy in response to the increase in the output gap generated by reforms in the short-run (e.g., Hughes-Hallett et al. (2004), Fitoussi and Saraceno (2004) • Limited amount of political capital (e.g., Eichengreen and Wyplosz (1998))
The LiteratureEvidence • Fiscal discipline on reforms • Helbling, Hakura, and Debrun (2004): ΔCAPB neg. related to labour market reforms, but no impact on product and labour market reforms. CAPB positively related to reforms. Data: 20 OECD countries, 1975-2000. Source: WEO(2004) • Heinemann (2006): ΔCAPB neg. related to labour market reforms, but no impact on product and labour market reforms. CAPB negatively related to labour market reforms. Data: 20 OECD countries, 1975-2000. Source: WEO(2004) • Duval and Elmeskov (2005): change in the CAB not significantly related to an indicator of labour and product market reforms, level of budget balancepositively related. Data: 21 OECD countries, 1985-2003. Source: OECD • Duval (2006): change in the CAB negatively related to an indicator of labour and product market reforms, level positively related. Data: 21 OECD countries, 1985-2003. Source: OECD • Reforms on budget balances • Deroose and Turrini (2005): small deterioration of budgets following labour market reforms, no impact of product market and pension reforms. Data: 14 EU countries, 1971-2002. Source: WEO(2004) and RDBF • Hoeller, Giorno and Van den Noord (2006): an indicator of labour and product market reforms significantly negatively related to primary cyclically-adjusted expenditure. Data: 21 OECD countries, 1985-2003. Source: OECD
ModelSet up • Country in a currency union; two periods (today, the future). • Output is determined by supply (Phillips curve) and demand in 1st period • Central bank sets nominal interest rates targeting (euro area) inflation. Credible commitment, conditional on 1st period information. • Long run (2nd period): output is supply determined and equal to potential. • Potential output is positively affected by structural reforms and negatively affected by deficits. • Governments decide about deficits and reforms after inflation expectations are formed
ModelBasic equations Aggregate demand Phillips curve Inflation targeting Potential output
ModelBasic equations Output (+) (+/-) Government problem Two types of government: Forward looking (high β) Myopic (low β)
ModelBasic results Stricter fiscal constraints (a higher γ1) may either increase or reduce structural reforms. Myopia matters: myopic governments give less weight to medium-long term substitution relationship between reforms and fiscal discipline (both good for Y2* , both costly in the short-run) Myopic government Forward-looking government
Does Maastricht clash with the Lisbon objectives?Some simulation results
Empirical analysisData • Labour market reforms: structural indexes from WEO (2004) • Construction: Average of employment restriction, unemployment benefit replacement rate and benefit duration indexes. Original source: Nickell and Nunziata (2001) • Coverage: 1970-1998, EU-14 excl. EL • Reform indicator: y-o-y change in index> median positive change • Myopia indicator: election in current or forthcoming year
Empirical analysisImplementation • Specification : reduced form Reforms = f (fiscal variables, cycle, structural factors, election variables, EMU dummy) Structural factors = country-specific time trends Coefficient of EMU dummy allowed to vary with degree of government myopia • Estimation method: Probit regression
Empirical analysisResults (III) • High debt ratio and lagged output gap positively associated with the probability of reforms • EMU dummy significantly negative (positive) for forward-looking (myopic) governments • EMU dummy significantly different for myopic and forward-looking governments only provided debt is high • Robustness checks: • Structural factors: country specific time ternds vs. fixed effects vs. lagged labour market structural indicator • Specifications eliminating variables likely to be correlated with EMU variable (debt, change in CAPB) • OLS vs. Probit
Conclusions and policy implications • The time horizon of governments and the general state of public finances are key in the complementairity/substitution relation between fiscal discipline and reforms • Empirical evidence shows the run up to EMU had a different impact on the reform stance of governments close to or far from elections • The reformed SGP allows for (limited) flexibility in the event of reforms. Implications from the analysis • Early years of EMU: deterioration in budgetary positions and lower reforms. All caused by weak cycle or evidence of increasing myopia? • Would a more lenient application of the SGP to high-debt countries facing elections yield more structural reforms?