1 / 22

A misplaced role for cost effectiveness analysis in the economic evaluation of public health?

A misplaced role for cost effectiveness analysis in the economic evaluation of public health?. David Cohen University of Glamorgan Funding from Welsh Assembly Government Wanless Health Economics Programme. Some background.

lara
Download Presentation

A misplaced role for cost effectiveness analysis in the economic evaluation of public health?

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. A misplaced role for cost effectiveness analysis in the economic evaluation of public health? David Cohen University of Glamorgan Funding from Welsh Assembly Government Wanless Health Economics Programme

  2. Some background • WAG funds Wanless Health Economics Programme bringing together health economists with an interest in public health • Agree that first task should be to commission systematic review of economic evaluations of public health • LSE review shows only 2.5% of studies meeting inclusion criteria are cost benefit analyses • WAG funds further work from Glamorgan (Cohen), Bangor (Edwards), Aberdeen (Lubrooke) and Brunel (Fox-Rushby)

  3. Evidence Based Medicine • Need for EBM recognised at least 20 years ago • Broad acceptance that the evidence base must also include economic evidence • Medical treatments are provided by NHS • (Principle) aim of treatment is to produce health • Key economic question addressed by NICE = how can NHS use its resources to maximise health output?

  4. But….. • There are many ways of producing health that do not involve medicine (NHS) • housing • environment • road safety • occupational health and safety • food policies • smoking policies • health promotion • etc., etc, etc, etc. • These all produce health by reducing the incidence/severity of preventable illness/injury

  5. What is health economics ? A couple of good definitions • “Health economics is the application of the discipline and tools of economics to the subject matter of health” (Culyer, 1981) • “The study of how people and organisations make use of scarce resources and the rewards achieved in terms of health” (Earl-Slater, 1999) An example of a bad definition • “Health economics is a discipline that analyses the economic aspects of the healthcare industry, using methods and theories from economics and medicine” (Kielhorn and Graf von der Schulenburg, 2000) • According to this definition health economics has no role to play in public health

  6. Two very different types of efficiency • Allocative efficiency - Should we do it? • Technical: - How should we do it? Different techniques of economic evaluation are used to address these different economic questions. They produce very different economic evidence

  7. Cost Benefit Analysis (CBA) • Concerned with allocative efficiency • “Should we allocate scarce resources to this intervention?” • CBA addresses this question by identifying all costs and benefits, measuring them and then expressing them in money values • If value of all benefits exceeds value of all the sacrifices (costs) then social welfare is increased and the programme should be introduced

  8. Cost Effectiveness Analysis (CEA) • Concerned with technical efficiency • Compares alternative ways of achieving an outcome • Outcome measured in natural units e.g. • smokers who quit • life years saved • QALYs • “What is the technically most efficient way of …..?” • CEA results only of use within the area in question e.g. smoking cessation • CUA extends this to “what is the technically most efficient way of producing a QALY”

  9. But CUA often (normally) results in ambiguous conclusions • Clear conclusion = new intervention dominates (lower cost greater effect) • Ambiguous conclusion = neither dominates New interventions are most commonly both more effective and more costly So what do you do? • Do a CBA (is better outcome worth the higher cost?) • Derive an Incremental Cost Effectiveness Ratio (ICER) and apply some rule of thumb

  10. Evidence based medicine • Main benefit = health (so aim is to maximise health from available resources) • Therefore need evidence on the technical efficiency of interventions (hence NICE preference for CUA) • Most common result of CUA is non-dominance (ICER) • But whether we should incur the extra cost in order to achieve extra effect is an allocative efficiency issue • Tendency to address allocative efficiency with heuristics e.g. NICE says that an incremental cost / QALY > £30,000 is ‘too high a price to pay’ • Essentially, this works quite well for health care

  11. NICE heuristic says that ICER of < £20,000 is “worth paying” • But how can this be determined without identifying the magnitude of the opportunity cost and who will bear it? • Example of herceptin for early stage breast cancer? • So might evidence on technical efficiency be leading to reduced allocative efficiency?

  12. Evidence based public health • Health care is clearly not the only way to produce health • Public health “… involves mobilising local, regional, national and international resources to create conditions in which people can be healthy” (Allin et al, 2004) • Improving the conditions in which people can be healthy can achieve important non-health benefits in addition to health

  13. Allocative v. technical efficiency • A CUA of a public health intervention (technical efficiency) would only include QALYs on the benefit side • If CUA shows high incremental cost/QALY, implication would be that resources should not be allocated • CBA on this same intervention which included non-health benefits might show it to pass the CB benefit test • Therefore a policy decisions taken on basis of CUA might not be optimal from a social welfare perspective

  14. CBA of policy to reduce air pollution CUA CBA Costs BenefitsCosts Benefits £--- QALYs £--- £a Health £--- £--- £b Cleaner air £--- £--- Total benefit = £Z £--- £--- Total cost = £X £--- Total cost = £Y • If CUA produces ICER > £30k message = policy is not ‘cost effective’ • But if £Y< £Z then adoption of the policy produces welfare gain • £Y< £b then policy increases social welfare even without health benefits

  15. So what’s the problem? • If % of PH interventions producing non-health benefits is high compared with health care interventions, then the PH evidence base should include a higher % of CBA studies than health care • But in a systematic review by the LSE (McDaid & Needle 2007) 73% (1235 of 1697) economic studies in PH (73%) were CEA/CUA • Only 43 (2.5%) were CBA • The rest were (mainly) cost consequences analyses • Aim of our exercise: to identify the non-health benefits in economic studies in LSE review which were not CEA/CUA and consider these with respect to the health benefits included in the CEA/CUA studies

  16. Finding useful papers • Identified papers = 462 • Abstract not available =19 • Abstract read = 333 • Full paper appeared useful by could not be retrieved =52 • Full papers read = 58 • Of these CBA = 10 CCA = 26 Multi-method = 14 Others = 8

  17. Examples of non-health benefits identified • Avoided damage to buildings • Increased agricultural output • Improved climate change • Lower crime rates • Increased productivity • Higher number graduating high school • Higher housewives output • Avoided pain and grief • Avoided loss of leisure time • Savings criminal justice system • Transportation savings • Reduction in property damage • Savings from professional services • Avoided special education

  18. A (fairly predictable) conclusion • Many PH interventions produce non-health benefits and these can be significant • Therefore many PH interventions need to be assessed by CBA • But number of CBA studies in PH is tiny • So one conclusion = we need more CBAs in PH

  19. Q: Why don’t we see more CBAs in PH A: It’s bloody difficult But saying we will do A because B is difficult can be exceedingly dangerous because the message from A can be very different from the message from B

  20. A possible way forward • Identify those PH interventions which have the greatest need for a CBA • Suggest doing this by placing intervention on a continuum from solely to incidentally health focused - solely health focused (e.g. adding folic acid to flour) - mainly health focused (e.g. road safety) - partly health focused (e.g. drugs and alcohol) - incidentally health focused (e.g. macroeconomic policies)

  21. But CUA of even a solely health focused intervention (e.g. folic acid) • would not include short term effects e.g. reassurance to women of childbearing age from the knowledge that consuming fortified food reduces risk of conceiving baby with NTD • Unlikely to include non-NHS resource savings e.g. special education plus the tangible and intangible benefits to parents of not having a disabled child. • CUA might lead to forgoing of welfare gains – but not a major problem because these will be relatively small • The further along the continuum, the greater the likelihood that decisions based on CUA results will not be socially optimal

  22. Overall Message • Much PH produces non-health benefits • Choice of economic evaluation technique should begin by examining the anticipated ratio of non-health to health benefits • Higher the ratio, stronger the argument to evaluate by CBA • High ratio PH interventions which are assessed by CUA should be treated with caution

More Related