160 likes | 282 Views
Does the Village Fund Matter in Thailand?. Regional Seminar on Poverty Monitoring and Evaluation Nanchang, China, May 11-12, 2007 Presenter: Shahid Khandker, World Bank. In 2001 the VRF was introduced in Thailand. Purpose was:
E N D
Does the Village Fund Matter in Thailand? Regional Seminar on Poverty Monitoring and Evaluation Nanchang, China, May 11-12, 2007 Presenter: Shahid Khandker, World Bank
In 2001 the VRF was introduced in Thailand • Purpose was: • To provide 1 million Baht ($22,500) to every village and urban community • Stimulate local economy by targeting new activities • A total injection of $1.75 billion in 74,000 villages & 4,500 urban communities • By May 2005, the VRF disbursed $6.9 billion to 17.8 million borrowers (an average loan size of $387) • It is the largest micro-credit scheme • Thailand has also an extensive network of rural lending by BAAC
How does VRF work? • Village funds are locally run and have some discretion in setting interest rates, maximum loan amounts, and terms of loans. • Village Funds are a revolving fund managed by village fund committees who do not handle money directly. • Funds are handled by a number of intermediaries such as Government Savings Bank (GSB) mostly in urban areas, and BAAC in rural and semi-urban areas. • The village first sets up a local committee and gets it registered and opens an account with the intermediary. The government then deposits a million baht into the account. • By May 2005, 99.1% of all villages had a VRF in operation and 98.3% of the originally scheduled amount had been distributed.
Scope of the VRF impact study • What is the impact of VRF on participants? • Who benefits more from the VRF program and in what way? • Given the presence of BAAC, what additional role VRF played in Thailand? • What lessons to be learned from this experiment?
Data– SES 2004 • 34,843 households were interviewed from 2,044 municipalities and 1,596 villages • One sixth of 69,486 adult members borrowed from VRF at least once with higher proportion among the poor and rural areas • Interest rate was about 6 percent • Equal share (50%) of VRF loan in agriculture and non-agriculture • Loan default was about 8 percent • Some 70% among borrowers believed VRF helped improve their economic situation
Propensity-score Matching (PSM) Propensity-score matching match on the basis of the probability of participation. • Ideally we would match on the entire vector X of observed characteristics. However, this is practically impossible. X could be huge. • Rosenbaum and Rubin: match on the basis of the propensity score = • This assumes that participation is independent of outcomes given X. If no bias given X then no bias given P(X).
Steps in Score Matching • SES 2004 is representative, highly comparable, surveys of the non-participants and participants; • (ii)Estimate a logit/ probit model of program participation: • Predicted values are “propensity scores.” • (iii)Restrict samples to assure common support; • (iv) Failure of common support is an important • source of bias in observational studies • (Heckman et al.).
Density of scores for non-participants Density of scores for participants
(v) For each participant find a sample of non-participants that have similar propensity scores; (vi) Compare the outcome indicators. The difference is the estimate of the gain due to the program for that observation; (vii) Calculate the mean of these individual gains to obtain the average overall gain. -Various weighting schemes.
Propensity score results • VRF borrowers are substantially poorer than non-borrowers • Borrowers are likely to be farmers, self-employed, come from North-West Region, have large family size and more earners per household • Given fixed amount of VRF per village, households living in a larger village are less likely to receive a VRF loan than those living in a small village • Education plays a positive role in obtaining VRF loans and participation
Average treatment effects of VRF participation • VRF borrowing helps increase per capita expenditure by 5.5% and per capita income by 4.4% • An average increase of income by 220 baht per month and expenditure by 200 baht • This rise in income implies a 17.6 percent rate of return to borrowing • Rates of increase in income and consumption are more for the poor than for the non-poor • Much of the effects are via farm income • Farm income rises by 40 percent compared to 9 percent in non-farm income • VRF is not a consumer credit nor a conduit necessarily for non-farm income growth • Our results are consistent with other findings based on panel of 960 households from rural Thailand (Kaboski and Townsend)
BAAC versus VRF • Of households covered in 2004, • ---23% borrowed from VRF only • ---15% from both VRF and BAAC • ---6% from BAAC only • Those who borrow BAAC are slightly poorer and substantially dependent on farm income • Borrowing from either BAAC or VRF only has small gains compared to borrowing from both sources • BAAC plus VRF raises expenditure by 9 percent and income by 8.5 percent. • Many BAAC households are likely to be credit constrained and thus, VRF plays an important complementary role
Conclusions • No method is perfect • Alternative methods are desired to verify results • Difference-in-difference method to be applied using panel data • Instrumental variable method can also be applied • Results seem to be conclusive that VRF matters in Thailand, helps the poor more, and works more for rural than urban areas.