110 likes | 174 Views
Analyze consumption externality and efficiency by solving for equilibrium prices and allocation using general equilibrium. Explore source of inefficiency in incomes and demands. Study method involves Lagrangean and Walras' Law to find equilibrium price ratio and allocation. Investigate Pareto improvement for inefficient allocation and explore tweaks for efficiency.
E N D
Exercise 9.1 MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell March 2007
Ex 9.1(1): Question • purpose: Analyse consumption externality and efficiency • method: Solve for equilibrium prices and allocation using standard GE. Then examine source of inefficiency
Ex 9.1(1): incomes and demands • The term x1a is irrelevant to b-people's behaviour • they cannot do anything about it… • …although it affects their utility • Incomes are • ya = 300 p1 • ya = 200 p2 • Both types have Cobb-Douglas utility functions • so we could jump straight to demand functions… • …skip the Lagrangean step • We know that their demands will be given by • x1*a = ½ ya / p1 , x2*a = ½ ya / p2 • x1*b = ½ yb / p1 , x2*b = ½ yb / p2 Skip Lagrangean
Ex 9.1(1): Lagrangean method • Lagrangean for either type can be written • kx1h x2h + n[yh p1x1h p2 x2h ] • where n is a Lagrange multiplier • k is a constant (k =1 for type a , k =1/x1a for type b) • FOC for an interior maximum • kx2h np1 = 0 • kx1h np2 = 0 • yh p1x1h p2 x2h= 0 • Substitute from FOC1, FOC2 into FOC3 to find n • yh p1[np2 /k] p2[np1 /k] = 0 • n= ½kyh /p1p2 • Substitute this value of n back into FOC2, FOC1 to get the demands: • x1*h = ½ yh / p1 • x2*h = ½ yh / p2
Ex 9.1(1): Equilibrium price ratio • Total demand for commodity 1 is • N [ x1*a + x1*b ] = N [ ½ ⋅300 + ½ ⋅ 200/r ] • where N is the large unknown number of traders • and r := p1 / p2 • only the price ratio matters in the solution • There are 300N units of commodity 1 • So the excess demand function for commodity 1 is • E1 = [150 + 100/r ] N 300 N • = [100/r 150] N • To find equilibrium sufficient to put E1 = 0 • if E1 = 0 then E2 = 0 also • by Walras' Law • Clearly E1 = 0 exactly where r = ⅔ • the equilibrium price ratio
Ex 9.1(1): Equilibrium allocation • Take the equilibrium price ratio r = ⅔ • Then, using the demand functions we find • x1*a = ½⋅300 = 150 • x2*a = ½⋅ 300r = 100 • x1*b = ½⋅ 200 / r = 150 • x2*b = ½⋅ 200 = 100 • This is the equilibrium allocation
Ex 9.1(2): Question method: • Verify that CE allocation is inefficient by finding a perturbation that will produce a Pareto improvement
Ex 9.1(2): Source of inefficeincy • It is likely that the a-people are consuming “too much” of good 1 • there is a negative externality • in the CE this is ignored • So try changing the allocation • so that the a-people consume less of good 1 • Dx1a < 0 • but where the a-people's utility remains unchanged • The means that their consumption of good 2 must increase • given that, in equilibrium, r = MRS, • required adjustment is Dx2a = −rDx1a >0
Ex 9.1(2): Pareto-improving adjustment • b-people's consumptions move in the opposite direction • (there is a fixed total amount of each good) • Dx1b = −Dx1a > 0 • Dx2b = −Dx2a < 0 • Effect on their utility can be computed thus: Dlog Ub = Dx1b / x1b + Dx2b / x2b− Dx1a /x1a = [ − 1/150 + ⅔(1/100) − 1/150] Dx1a = − Dx1a / 150 >0 • So it is possible to make a Pareto-improving perturbation • move away from the CE • in such a way that some people's utility is increased • no-one else's utility decreases
Ex 9.1(3): Question and answer • Can this be done by just tweaking prices? • increase relative price of commodity 1 for the a-people… • …relative to that facing the b-people? • This will not work • a-people’s income is also determined by p1 … • …and their resulting consumption of commodity 1 is independent of price • A rationing scheme may work
Ex 9.1: Points to remember • Be careful to model what is under each agent’s control • Use common-sense to spot Pareto improvements