310 likes | 419 Views
Employing Market Mechanisms to Manage Spectrum Mark Bykowsky and William Sharkey. FCC Office of Strategic Planning and Policy Analysis Kellogg School Conference: Spectrum Management: Challenges Ahead June 3, 2011. Market Mechanisms and Collective Decision Making in Spectrum Allocation.
E N D
Employing Market Mechanisms to Manage Spectrum Mark Bykowsky and William Sharkey FCC Office of Strategic Planning and Policy Analysis Kellogg School Conference: Spectrum Management: Challenges Ahead June 3, 2011
Market Mechanisms and Collective Decision Making in Spectrum Allocation • Coase (1959) first suggested that a market mechanism could efficiently assign spectrum rights to the highest bidder • More recently Benkler (1998), Lessig (2001), Reed (2002) and others have argued for a “commons” model for spectrum use • See also Coase (1974) and Faulhaber and Farber (2002)
Fundamental Question: Can market participants solve a variety of collective action problems that may be required to reach an efficient allocation and assignment of spectrum? • Licensed vs. unlicensed spectrum • Definition of other spectrum characteristics such as transmission power levels
Policy Question #1 • Does society have the “right” amount of spectrum designated to licensed and unlicensed operations? • “Right” is defined as that designation of spectrum across the two license regimes such that the value that society places on spectrum is maximized
Current Situation • Regulators employ an administrative process to determine whether spectrum should be designated to either licensed or unlicensed operations • Incentive Problem: Interested parties have an incentive to mis-represent the value they place on a given license regime
One Potential Solution • Induce interested parties to reveal more truthfully the value they place on a given license regime by creating a “market” for licensing rules • Define a New Auction Form: An auction that simultaneously determines the “auction winner(s)” and the license rules that are associated with the sold spectrum
Impediments to a Market-based Solution • Efficiency requires inducing parties to reveal enough information about the value they place on a particular licensing regime • Valuations may be too high if bidders desire to acquire spectrum for strategic reasons (e.g., entry deterrence) • Given the common pool nature of unlicensed operations, efficiency may require solving an important “collective action problem” • Beneficiaries of unlicensed operations may excessively “free-ride”
Economic Analysis • Employ economic theory and experimental analysis to examine whether a market can be used to determine the efficient set of auction winners and the efficient license regime assigned to several blocks of spectrum
A Stylized Example • Four new blocks of spectrum available • Two bidders (L-type) are interested in acquiring ownership of either one or two blocks for their exclusive use • Six bidders (U-type) are interested in bidding for one or two blocks to be managed as a “common property” resource
Market Description • Participants place bids conditional on their preferred license regime • Bidders who prefer to have spectrum designated to unlicensed use place “U-type” bids, which will be subsequently aggregated • The highest L-type bid is compared to the sum of the U-type bids • Comparison not only determines the auction winners, but also the use to which spectrum is designated • Bidders who desire licensed (fully private) spectrum, bid as in current auctions by placing “L-type” bids
Pricing Rules • Various rules can be used to define prices paid by winning bidders • First price • Second price • Clarke-Groves • Each of the four blocks of spectrum is sold at a single, uniform price. L-Type winners pay this price • U-Type winners pay a price that is proportional to the contribution they made to the U-Type winning bid
L - Bidder for 1st Block L - Bidder for 2nd Block U - Bidder for 1st Block U - Bidder for 2nd Block Subject Valuations(Environment #1) Value 400 300 A A 200 B A B 100 C D C D E F E F G H 400 300 250 200 120 120 80 80 60 60 40 G H Spectrum Blocks
L - Bidder for 1st Block L - Bidder for 2nd Block U - Bidder for 1st Block U - Bidder for 2nd Block Efficient Assignment(Environment #1) Valuations 500 Supply #8 H A 400 G #7 #6 F B 300 H #8 A #5 E G #7 F B #6 200 #5 2 E D #4 #4 D 100 #3 C C #3 =440 400 300 400 300 =280 250 200 4 Spectrum Blocks
Nash Equilibria Selection Problem • Assume that each bidder has complete information about the number of bidders, bidder valuations, and bidder “type” • It can be shown that, for a given set of valuations, both the efficient and numerous inefficient assignments can be sustained as Nash equilibria • Total surplus and individual payoffs vary substantially across the different Nash equilibria • There are three “types” of Nash Equilibria. Game theory is silent on which type of equilibrium is most likely to be selected
Valuations 500 Supply A 400 B L - Bidder for 1st Block 300 A L - Bidder for 2nd Block U - Bidder for 1st Block B 200 C-H U - Bidder for 2nd Block Price C-H 100 400 250 <200 <200 250 201 Spectrum Blocks Type 0 Nash Equilibrium(Environment #1) 4
L - Bidder for 1st Block L - Bidder for 2nd Block U - Bidder for 1st Block U - Bidder for 2nd Block Type 1 Nash Equilibrium(Environment #1) Valuations 500 Supply A 400 B 300 A C-H C-H B Price 200 2 100 =200 250 250 400 Spectrum Blocks 4
Valuations 500 Supply C-H #8 A 400 L - Bidder for 1st Block B L - Bidder for 2nd Block 300 C-H U - Bidder for 1st Block A Price U - Bidder for 2nd Block B 200 2 100 #3 =440 400 300 =280 400 300 250 200 4 Spectrum Blocks Type 2 Nash Equilibrium(Environment #1)
Experimental Methodology • Define an economic environment (e.g., # blocks of spectrum, # of bidders of each type, rights associated with each license regime, information assumptions) • Assign human subjects a “role” (L-type or S-type) and a willingness to pay for one or more blocks of spectrum • Use financial payments to motivate subject behavior • Identify the efficient designation of spectrum to licensed and unlicensed operations and compare it to the observed spectrum allocation generated in the experiment • Change the economic environment (i.e., participant valuations) and compare the observed designation of spectrum with the efficient designation
Policy Question #2 • Can market forces be used to obtain an efficient allocation of signal interference rights? • Example: An incumbent license holder (E-type firm) seeks permission to offer “enhanced service” at higher transmitting power than currently authorized • License holders in spectrally adjacent bands (S-type firms) may be harmed by increased signal interference
Environment 1: No Enforceable Property Rights • An auction is held to determine whether or not to authorize an increase in transmission power • The E-type firm and each S-type firm simultaneously bid an amount representing their alleged benefit or harm • Enhanced service at higher power is authorized if and only if the E-bid is greater than the collective bids of S-type firms
Bidder #2 Strategies $3 $5 $6 ($6) $8 $4 ($8) $6 $6 Bidder #1 Strategies $4 ($8) $6 $4 ($8) $6 $4 Environment 1: No Enforceable Property RightsCase 1: E-Bid = $10
Bidder #2 Strategies $3 $5 $8 ($6) $8 $6 ($6) $8 $6 Bidder #1 Strategies $6 ($6) $10 $4 ($10) $6 $4 Environment 1: No Enforceable Property RightsCase 1: E-Bid = $8
Environment 2: S-Type Firms Have a Right to Non-Inteference • E-type firms makes an offer to compensate each S-type firm for alleged harm • Each S-type firm submits an ask price representing harm from interference • Enhanced service is authorized if a mutually satisfactory compensation scheme is agreed upon
Environment 2: Property Right in Non-InterferenceCase 1: E-Bid = $18 Licensee #2 Ask Price $12 $8 $12.2 ($12.5) $15.3 $11 ($6) $14 $9 Licensee #1 Ask Price $11 ($6) $14 $11 ($6) $14 $13
Environment 2: Property Right in Non-InterferenceCase 1: E-Bid = $22 Licensee #2 Ask Price $12 $8 $13.2 ($10.5) $16.3 $16.3 ($8.5) $15.2 $9 Licensee #1 Ask Price $12.2 ($8.5) $19.3 $11 ($6) $14 $13
Concluding Comments • “Collective Action Problems” underlie a wide variety of spectrum policy problems • Bidders for a common property use of spectrum • Incumbent license rule enhancement problem • “Treshhold problem” when independent bidders must bid against a rival bidder who wishes to purchase a collection of multiple geographic blocks • 700 MHz C-block “open” platform requirement • Re-assigning broadcast spectrum to alternative uses
References • Bykowsky, Mark M., Mark Olson, and William W. Sharkey (2010), “Efficiency Gains from Using a Market Approach to Spectrum Management,” Information Economics and Policy, 22: 73-90 • Bykowsky, Mark M. and William W. Sharkey (2011), “Using a Market to Obtain the Efficient Allocation of Signal Interference Rights,” unpublished • Benkler, Yochai (1998), “Overcoming Agoraphobia: Building the Commons of the Digitally Networked Environment, Harv. J. L & Tech., 287 • Coase, Ronald H. (1959), “The Federal Communications Commission,” Journal of Law & Economics, 2: 1-40 • Coase, Ronald H. (1974), "The Lighthouse in Economics", Journal of Law and Economics 17: 357–376 • Faulhaber, Gerald R. and David J. Farber (2002), “Spectrum Management: Property Rights, Markets, and The Commons,” AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Working Paper 02-12 • Lessig, Lawrence (2001), The Future of Ideas: The Fate of the Commons in a Connected World, Random House: New York • Reed, David, 2002, “Comments for FCC Spectrum Task Force on Spectrum Policy,” available at www.newamerica.net/files/archive/Doc_File_142_1.pdf • Sharkey, William W., Fernando Beltrán and Mark M. Bykowsky (2011), “Computational Analysis of an Auction for Licensed and Unlicensed Use of Spectrum,” unpublished