210 likes | 379 Views
AP ECONOMICS: Ch. 7,8,9 Review. MARKETS AND WELFARE. Alex Kunkel. Chapter 7: Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets. The study of market allocation Analysis using positive statements (how it is) and normative statements (how it ought to be)
E N D
AP ECONOMICS:Ch. 7,8,9 Review MARKETS AND WELFARE Alex Kunkel
Chapter 7: Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets • The study of market allocation • Analysis using positive statements (how it is) and normative statements (how it ought to be) • Welfare economics – the study of how the allocation of resources affects economic well-being • Willingness to pay – the maximum amount that a buyer will pay for a good
Example of Willingness to Pay Principle and Consumer Surplus • Say I want to sell a guitar for $1000. • I have four potential buyers at an auction; Jimi, Angus, Pete, and Tom. • Jimi has $250, Angus has $500, Pete has $900 and Tom has $1200. • Tom and I agree on $1000 as the price. • As a result Tom has a consumer surplus of $200, due to paying $1000 for a good he values at $1200. • Hypothetically, if I chose to be a bit greedier and sell the guitar for $1500, Tom would chose not to buy it because it is more than he is willing to pay. He would be an example of a marginal buyer in that case. • Consumer Surplus – the amount a buyer is willing to pay for a good minus the amount the buyer actually pays for it.
Cost – the value of everything a seller must give up to produce a good. (For example the guitar cost me $1100 when I bought it.) • Producer Surplus – the amount a seller is paid for a good minus the seller’s cost of providing it. • Efficiency – the property of a resource allocation of maximizing the total surplus received by all members of society. • Equality – the property of distributing economic prosperity uniformly among the members of society Note: This is not an actual graph
Some Equations • Consumer Surplus = Value to buyers – amount paid by buyers • Producer Surplus = amount received by sellers – cost to sellers • Total surplus = (values to buyers – amount paid by buyers) + (Amount received by sellers – cost to sellers) • Total surplus = value to buyers – cost to sellers
Insights toward Market Equilibrium • Free markets allocate the supply of goods to the buyers who value them most highly, as measured by their willingness to pay. • Free markets allocate the demand for goods to the sellers who can produce them at the least cost • Free markets produce the quantity of goods that maximizes the sum of consumer and producer surplus • At quantities less than equilibrium the value to buyers exceeds the cost to sellers. • At quantities greater than equilibrium the cost tot sellers exceeds the value to buyers. • Market equilibrium maximizes the sum of producer and consumer surplus.
Market Efficiency and Failure • In the analysis of welfare economics, consumer and producer surplus are shown to evaluate efficiency. In a “perfect” market, Adam Smith’s “Invisible hand” theory guides this efficiency • In certain markets a seller may be able to control prices (cough, cough monopoly) • These “certain sellers” have market power, and some side effects called externalities may occur due to inefficiency.
Chapter 8: The Costs of Taxation • “Taxes are what we pay for civilized society” – Oliver Wendell Holmes Jr. • “Nothing is true but death and taxes” – Ben Franklin
Effects of Taxes • Taxes place a “wedge” of deadweight loss in the market, this due to its added cost of the purchase of a good. This varies on whether the tax is on consumers or producers. Either way it creates unwanted fall in total surplus, due to extra money spent on good/raw material. That is why taxes can be considered a “market distortion” from the normal price/cost. • Tax revenue equals Tax multiplied by quantity. • Taxes cause deadweight loss because they prevent buyers and sellers from realizing some of the gains from trade. It it the lost gain from trade.
Tax Distortions and Elasticity • What determines the size of deadweight loss from a tax that is large or small? • The elasticity of supply and demand can further distort the size of tax. • When supply is relatively inelastic, the deadweight loss of the tax is small. • When supply is relatively elastic, the deadweight loss of a tax is large. • When demand is relatively inelastic, the deadweight loss of a tax is small • When demand is relatively elastic, the deadweight loss of tax is large. • The graph to the right shows the distribution of tax due to price elasticity. • In overview, the greater the elasticity of supply and demand, the greater the deadweight loss caused by the tax.
Deadweight Loss due to Tax Size; Laffer Curve • With larger taxes, the deadweight loss caused by its application is much higher, and tax revenue is very slim. • With smaller taxes the deadweight loss is quite small, but tax revenue isn’t as big as the Feds would like. • A medium tax would settle this difference • This is shown in the Laffer Curve, which demonstrates the trade-off caused through tax revenues and tax size. • It caused the government to realize the cut in tax rates would allow an increased production. This application to taxes became known as supply-side economics.
Of course some transactions occur illegally through the underground economy, which is of course where taxes don’t apply and most transactions involve illegal goods. • These “career criminals” that engage in this compare the opportunity cost before them; they can earn more through breaking the law rather than with a wage they could earn legitimately. Risk aversion is mostly low. • A good example of a rise in the “underground economy” is during Prohibition. (Note: Al Capone, Meyer Lansky, and Arnold Rothstein; Organized Crime Kingpins during Prohibition) (Rothstein is also noted as the man that fixed the 1919 World Series)
No International Trade • With no given international trade, the price adjusts to balance domestic supply and demand, as shown for a random good. • With international trade the price of a good on international level will prevail the domestic price. This is called the world price.
Trade • With a country that has a higher domestic price for a good, that country will import goods due to the lower world price. • With a country that has a lower domestic price for a good, that country will export goods to make profit from this international trade. • The areas represented show the consumer and producer surplus, and the imports or exports.
Tariffs • However, in some cases, domestic governments will impose a tax on foreign goods coming into their country. This is a tariff. • In most cases it causes domestic producers to not be completely undercut in competition by cheaper priced foreign goods. • Tariffs provide a further deadweight loss, which increases cost from world price. • The argument on tariffs and international trade is continuous.
Benefits of International Trade • Increased variety of goods – free trade allows consumers a wider choice, greater variety and quality. • Lower costs through economies of scale – some goods are produced at low cost only at large quantities. Free trade allows access to these world markets. • Increased competition – When shielded from foreign competition, a firm has much more control over domestic markets and prices. Free trade allows the “invisible hand” to reach a much larger spectrum. • Enhanced flow of ideas – Technological advances around the world are best linked to trade. Ideas flow on a bigger scale. • Those who argue against free trade say there are benefits that would arise from closing off world markets as well, but isn’t widely supported. Some of these arguments include off-shoring of jobs, national security (with certain traded goods), the “infant-industry” (newer companies attempting to enter the global market) and unfair competition through undercutting prices.